Notes
Notes
This course assumes knowledge of statistical and actuarial functions associated with a
single life, as far as the calculation of premium rates using the equivalence principle.
Some of these concepts are reviewed here.
When a life effects a policy, like a life insurance policy which pays out a lump sum on death,
the actual future lifetime is unknown.
We represent this future lifetime of a life aged x by a random variable Tx . Some of the
important characteristics of Tx are as follows.
Sx (t) = 1 − Fx (t)
1
.
In actuarial notation:
t qx = Fx (t) t px = Sx (t)
and t qx + t px = 1.
P{Tx ≤ t + h | Tx > t}
µx+t = lim
h→0 h
2
Fx (t + h) − Fx (t)
= lim
h→0 h (1 − Fx (t))
h qx+t
= lim
h→0 h
d
− dt t px
= .
p
t x
Therefore:
d
t px = −fx (t) = −t px µx+t
dt
and since:
d
d dt t px
log (t px ) =
dt t px
we get:
Zt
3
(d) If we know the p.d.f. of Tx we can calculate moments of Tx :
Z∞
◦
E[Tx ] = ex = t px dt
t=0
The probabilities t px are usually computed with the aid of a life table.
By considering a starting age αand a radix lα which represents the number of people
alive at age αwe define the life table function lx at all ages x ≥ αby:
lx = x−α pα lα .
4
which represents the expected numberof these same people alive at age x. Therefore:
lx+t
t px = .
lx
The random variable Kx = int[Tx ], the integer part of Tx , defines the start of the year of
death (measured from age x). The random variable Kx + 1defines the end of the year
of death.The same life table probabilities t px , with integer values of t, serve to define the
(discrete-valued) distribution of Kx and Kx + 1. In fact, the term ‘life table’ usually refers
to the tabulation of lx at integer ages x.
Payments made on death, or as long as someone still lives, are made at random times,
because Tx is a random variable. Given a force of interest δ , the present values of such
payments are therefore also random variables. For example the present value of $1
payable immediately on death is:
exp(−δTx ) = v Tx
5
and the present value of $1 payable at the end of the year of death is:
exp(−δ(Kx + 1)).
The expectations of such present values (EPVs)are important in pricing life insurance
contracts. Many are given special symbols in the international actuarial notation. For
example:
Āx = E[exp(−δTx )]
Ax = E[exp(−δ(Kx + 1))].
Similar EPVs (āx , ax , äx , etc., may be defined in respect of level annuity payments.
There are many variants of such symbols to deal with limited terms, deferred payment,
frequency of paymentand other simple variants.
6
The Principle of Equivalenceis often used to calculate premiums. It states that:
Ax = Px äx
is solved to find Px , the premium for a whole-life assurance of $1, payable at the end of the
year of death to a life age x, with premiums payable annually in advance for life.
Standard EPVs can be calculated exactly for benefits payable at the end of the year of life,
or annuities payable annually, using a standard life table, for example:
t=∞
X
Ax = e−δ(t+1) t px qx+t
t=0
7
t=∞
X
äx = e−δt t px .
t=0
When benefits are payable at the moment of death, or annuities are payable continuously,
EPVs can be expressed exactly as integrals, for example:
Z t=∞
Āx = e−δt t px µx+t dt
t=0
Z t=∞
āx = e−δt t px dt
t=0
but these integrals may have to be evaluated approximately using numerical methods.
Such numerical methods (generally needing a computer) were not covered in Intro to LIM
but will be very important in LIM1.
8
2 Policy Values and Reserves
[Handout to accompany this section: reprint of ‘Life Insurance’, from The Encyclopaedia of Actuarial
Science, John Wiley, Chichester, 2004.]
Every enterprise, life offices included, needs a balance sheet showing the values of its
assets and its liabilities. If assets exceed liabilities in value, the company is solvent,
otherwise it is insolvent.
What are the values of the assets and liabilities of a life office?
• The majority of the assets will be investments such as bonds, equities and property.
They have been purchased with policyholders’ premiums and they will be held in a
fund from which benefits will be paid out.
• The liabilities are the promises made to pay benefits in future, against which can be set
9
the policyholders’ promises to pay premiums in future.
It is relatively easy to quantify the assets, since investments can be valued (e.g. bonds
and equities have a market value).The question is, how do we quantify or value the
liabilities?
The answer is: the actuary makes estimates of future interest rates, mortality and
possibly expenses — called a valuation basis — and using these, calculates the
assets required to meet the expected future payments to policyholders.The resulting
number is called a policy value. The total of all the policy values is then the liability shown
in the balance sheet.
The reserveis then the portfolio of assets held by an insurer in order to ensure that it can
meet its future liabilities. The reserve must be at least equal to the total of policy values.
An insurance company needs to hold a reserve in respect of a life insurance policy because
the premium income does not coincide with the benefits and expenses outgo.
The outgo usually increaseswith duration, whereas the premium income is usually level.
10
Example:
11
2.2 The Loss Random Variable, Lt , and its Mean
For a whole life policy issued to (x) with sum assured $1 and level annual premiums, the
annual premium payable given some mortality and interest assumptions (and ignoring
expenses), is:
Ax
Px = .
äx
EPV[benefits] = EPV[premiums]
Kx +1
E[v ] = E[Px äKx +1 ]
⇒ E[v Kx +1 ] − E[Px äKx +1 ] = 0
12
⇒ E[v Kx +1 − Px äKx +1 ] = 0.
Definition:
At any future time t, we define the random variable Lt , called the loss at time t, to be the
difference between the present values, at time t, of future outgo and of future income:
The expected value of this random variable is called the prospective policy value of the
contract at time t, and is denoted V (t).
As a specific example, the loss just before a premium payment date t is:
Lt = v Kx+t +1 − Px äKx+t +1
13
Therefore the prospective policy value at that time is:
(1) Convention: The policy value above was calculated just before the premium then due,
at an integer duration.It turns out that policy values of this kind make the formal
mathematics as simple as it is possible to make it, so it is often assumedthat policy values
are calculated just before premium due dateswhen working out the mathematics.
It is important to realise, however, that in practice a life office will usually have to calculate
the policy values for all its in-force business on a fixed calendar date.Only by coincidence
will this be an integer policy duration, for any randomly chosen policy.
(2) Policy values and reserves: There is a distinction between a policy value and a
reserve.
14
• A policy value is a number calculated by an actuary on the basis of some
assumptions about future mortality, interest, etc.
• Reserves are needed to pay surrender values to policy-holders who surrender, if the
policy terms allow the payment of a surrender benefit.
• Policy values and reserves are necessary for calculations related to policy alterations
and conversions.
For example, a policy-holder who has held a whole life policy for 8 years may request
to change the cover to that of an endowment assurance, if the policy terms allow.
15
• Policy values and reserves are important for demonstrating solvency.
On at least one fixed day each year life offices are required to show that they are
solvent by demonstrating that they have sufficient assets to set aside reserves at least
equal to the total of the policy values of their in-force business.
• For with-profit policies, policy values and reserves are used in determining bonus
levels.
(4) Valuation basis: The assumptions used to calculate a policy value — interest,
mortality and possibly expenses — are collectively called the valuation basis.
(5) Premium calculation: The calculation of premiums is a special case of the calculation
of policy values. We find the value of P for which the expected future loss at outset is
zero.
16
For the above example, this means:
(6) Boundary conditions for policy values: There are often simple and obvious
boundary conditions for policy values at outset and at the expiry of a policy.
• If the basis used to calculate the policy values and that used to calculate the premium
are the same, then:
V (0) = 0
• If a policy does not pay a benefit at maturity (e.g. an n-year term assurance policy),
17
then:
V (n) = 0
• For a policy paying out a maturity benefit of S after the expiry at time n, then:
V (n) = S
There are several different types of policy value, suitable for different purposes. The
simplest is the net premium policy value.We assume the valuation basis to be given.
(a) The premium used in the policy value calculation is not the gross premium (or
office premium) — we compute an artificial premium using the valuation
basis.This is called the valuation premium, the valuation net premium, or just the net
premium.
18
(b) Expenses are ignoredthroughout, indeed there are no expenses in a net premium
valuation basis.
(c) For with-profit policies, the benefits valued include any bonuses that have already
been declared. Future bonuses that have not been declared are ignored.
Until recently, in most European countries, it was mandatory that policy values be
calculated on a net premium basis.
Note: It is assumed that the difference between the “office premium” and the “net
premium” will cover the expenses and, in the case of with-profit policies, future bonuses. It
is therefore important to ensure that the net premium calculated and used is less than
the office premium being charged.
Net premiums policy values ignore certain features of the policy, such as the office
premium, expenses and future bonuses. In contrast, a gross premium policy valueallows
19
for all these features.
(a) we use the office premium (actual premium being paid)in the policy value
calculation.
(b) We include the EPV of future expenses.
(c) in the case of with-profit policies, the benefits valued should include any bonuses
already declared and some assumed level of future bonus declarations.
Consequently, a gross premium valuation basis will include assumed future levels of bonus
and expenses.
PVfuture loss
20
and its mean, the gross premium prospective policy value, is:
E[PVfuture loss ]
For with-profit policies, the gross premium prospective policy value, allowing for declared
and future bonuses, is:
Policy values calculated in this way are called bonus reserve policy values.
21
Expenses
In the expression for gross premium policy value we note that the sum assured, the
premiums and the bonuses are aspects of a policy that we have met before. When a
company quotes a premium, it would have calculated the premium under some
assumptions on the level and timing of future expenses. The company hopes that the
actual expenses will not exceed those assumed.
(a) Initial expenses: These are incurred at the outset or during the first few years and
can be particularly heavy, often exceeding the first or second years’ premiums in
value. Initial expenses are largely due to costs of paying commission, and head
office expenses like underwriting and setting up the policy on computer systems.
(b) Renewal expenses: These are incurred every year or month (perhaps except the
first) and are typically due to renewal commission, premium collection costs and
claims handling.
22
Expenses are expressed in one of the following ways:
(a) As per-policy expenses (e.g. $100). Per-policy expenses are not related to the level
of the benefit and may be subject to inflation.
(b) As a percentage of the premium.
(c) As a percentage of the benefit.
2.5 Notation
The standard actuarial notation for various kinds of policy may also be extended to policy
values using the symbol t V , where t is the duration, and appending the usual buscripts
and superscripts. For example:
23
Policy Premiums Policy Value
Whole-life Annual t Vx
(m)
Whole-life m-thly V
t x
and so on. However, we will just use the simpler notation V (t), leaving it to the context to
determine the type of policy, and modifying it whenever needed to distinguish between
different policies.
Consider a non-profit whole life policy issued to (x), with sum assured $1 payable at the
end of year of death.
Suppose premiums and reserves are calculated on the same basisand there are no
expenses. Hence the annual premium is Px = Ax /äx .
24
At time t since inception while the policy is still in force, the policy value is V (t).The office
is assumed to hold a reserve of assets equal in value to V (t).
If the life office earns interest on its assets at the rate assumed in the valuation basis,
denoted i, then at time t + 1, just before payment of any benefits then due, we have:
(V (t) + Px ) (1 + i)
(i) die — with probability qx+t — in which case the policy pays the sum assured of $1
(ii) survive — with probability px+t — in which case the reserve should be sufficient to
satisfy the policy value at time t + 1 i.e. V (t + 1).
Therefore we should expect (for we have not yet proved it) that:
25
Formal proof of the recursive relationship for a whole life policy.
26
Importance of recursive relationships.
(a) They can be interpreted as a statement about the evolution of the life office’s balance
sheet,thus: If the office invests in assets that earn the rate of return assumed in the basis,
and mortality and (possibly) expenses are also exactly as in the basis, then at all times
the office will hold assets exactly equal in value to the policy value, i.e. the liability.
(b) These recursive relationships are valid for all forms of benefit, even benefits that may
depend on the reserve.
(c) They define the policy values at non-integer durations.For example, consider a
whole-life policy issued to (x), with benefit $1 payable at the end of the year of death, and
annual premiums:
V (t + 0.75)(1 + i)0.25
= 0.25 qx+t+0.75 + 0.25 px+t+0.75 V (t + 1).
Note: For annual premium policies, premiums are payable at durations t and t + 1,
27
not t + 0.75.
(V (t) + Px ) (1 + i)0.75
Example: Consider a 30-year endowment sold to a life age 30, with death benefit payable
at the end of the year of death. Using A1967–70 ultimate mortality and 4% interest,
evaluate:
(i) V (4.5), assuming premiums are payable annually, given that V (5) = 0.099342.
(ii) V (14.75), assuming premiums are payable quarterly.
Solution:
28
(i) No premium is paid between t = 5 and t = 4.5, hence:
If we assume that the force of mortality is constant between integer ages, then:
29
(4)
(ii) Premiums are paid quarterly. Let P be the annual amount of premium, then:
30:30
(4) A30:30
P30:30 = (4)
= 0.01856
ä30:30
and:
(4) (4)
V (15) = A45:15 − P30:30 ä45:15 = 0.36284
If we assume a constant force of mortality between exact ages 44 and 45 we can calculate
30
0.25 p44.75 as:
1
0.25 p44.75 ≈ (p44 ) = 0.99416
4
V (14.75) = 0.35503.
31
2.7 Thiele’s differential equation.
When benefits are payable immediately on death, and premiums are paid continuously, the
recursive relationship between reserves becomes a differential equation, called Thiele’s
differential equation.We will derive it in the particular case of a whole-life non-profit
insurance, issued to (x), t years ago.We assume:
µx+t -
Alive Dead
6
6 Receive SA of 1
Premium P̄x p.a.
32
We suppose that the premium and valuation bases are the same, and are given by force of
interest δ and force of mortality µx+t . The policy value at time t years since policy
inception is again denoted V (t).
[Note: In standard actuarial notation, a bar is used to denote policy values in the
continuous model, e.g. t V̄x and t V̄x:n . We do not use this notation.]
33
V (t) + V (t) δ dt + P̄x dt.
Applying the same reasoning as explained the recursive relationships, if all goes exactly as
assumed in the bases, this should be just enough to cover the cost of paying expected
death claims, and setting up the required reserve at time t + dt. That is, it should be equal
to:
34
Divide by dt to get:
V (t + dt) − V (t)
= V (t) δ + P̄x
dt
−µx+t (1 − V (t + dt)).
We will need the following two results, whose proofs are tutorial questions:
35
āx+t
(2.1) V (t) = 1−
āx
d
(2.2) (āx+t ) = µx+t āx+t − Āx+t .
dt
Proof of Thiele:
d
V (t)
dt
d āx+t
= 1− using (2.1)
dt āx
1 d
= − āx+t
āx dt
1
= − µx+t āx+t − Āx+t using (2.2)
āx
āx+t 1 − δ āx+t
= −µx+t +
āx āx
36
1
= −µx+t (1 − V (t)) + − δ (1 − V (t))
āx
using (2.1)
1 − δ āx
= − µx+t (1 − V (t)) + + δ V (t)
āx
Āx
= − µx+t (1 − V (t)) + + δ V (t)
āx
= − µx+t (1 − V (t)) + P̄x + δ V (t).
37
3 Life Insurance and Differential Equations
Our model was specified by the assumption that the remaining lifetime at age x was a
random variable Tx with a continuous distribution. That distribution is completely described
if we know either:
Here, we assume the third of these is true: we are given the force of mortality at all ages.
We can visualise this with the following picture:
38
µx+t -
Alive Dead
The problem then becomes: given µx+t , how can we find all the probabilities and
EPVs needed to find premiums and policy values?
The answer lies in solving ordinary differential equations (ODEs). We have already seen
the following ODE which allows us to find survival probabilities:
d
t px = −t px µx+t .
dt
39
We will call this the Kolmogorov equationfor reasons that will become clear later.
Combined with the initial condition 0 px = 1,we wish to solve this for all t > 0.
We have also seen Thiele’s differential equation, which for a whole-life contract was:
d
V (t) = V (t)δ + P̄x − µx+t (1 − V (t)).
dt
This allows us to calculate policy values, but in fact the EPVs of any cashflows contingent
upon the model pictured above can be found. The boundary condition in this case is a
terminal conditionrather than an initial condition(we will see this in Section 3.5).
Very rarely, µx+t has such a simple form (e.g. a constant) that we can find explicit
solutions, i.e. simple formulaeto one of both of these ODEs. Nearly always, however, we
must solve them numerically, using a computer. We will do this using the simplest possible
method, an Euler scheme.
40
3.2 A comment on this approach
At first sight, this approach seems more complicated than just using a life table. Indeed it
is, moreover it is distinctly modern because before today’s computer power became
available, the numerical solution of ODEs was a formidable task.
The payoff will come later, when we consider more complicated contracts. Here is an
advance look at a model that underlies disability insurance, in which someone who is too
sick to work receives a regular income to replace their lost earnings.
41
ρx
State 1
State 2
Healthy - Sick
σx
@
@ µx νx
@R
@
State 3
Dead
We could try to formulate this model in terms of the random times at which events take
place, the analogues of the random lifetime Tx .This turns out to be extremely difficult
and complicated, and computing probabilities and EPVs by this approach is a nightmare.
But, if we take as given the ‘forces’ governing transitions between the three states, the
analogues of the force of mortality µx+t ,it turns out that versions of the Kolmogorov
equation and Thiele’s equation can be written down very easily, and solving them
42
numerically is just as easy as in the simple life-death model. That is why we take this
approach.
We show, below, how a simple recursive scheme Euler schemecan be used to solve an
ODE, given an initial condition.
43
f (t) = t px
This sets up an Euler scheme to solve the Kolmogorov equation, conditional on the life
being alive at age x.
First, we choose a suitable step size, denoted h.This should be as small as possible,
consistent with the computing capacity available. In the tutorials there is an opportunity to
experiment with different step sizes. For example, 0.1 year or 0.01 year might be chosen.
The Euler scheme advances the solution of the ODE in steps of length h, starting with the
initial condition. It does so by assuming that the function f (t) is approximately
linear.This assumption gets more reasonable as the step size decreases.
Suppose the solution has been advanced by k steps, that is, we have found approximate
44
values of
f (h), f (2h), . . . , f (kh).
If f (t) actually was linear on [kh, (k + 1)h],it would be a straight line with slope f ′ (t),
and the following would be exactly true:
Although f (t) is not, in general, linear anywhere (certainly not in the case of the
Kolmogorov equation representing human mortality) if the step size h is small enough, the
error we make by assuming f (t) to be approximately linear may be small enough to be
acceptable. Therefore, we apply Equation (3.3) successively, starting with the initial
condition f (0). This is the Euler scheme.
45
3.4 Solving the Kolmogorov equation
d
h px ≈ 0 px + h t px
dt t=0
= 0 px + h [−0 px µx+0 ]
= 1 − h µx
and:
d
2h px ≈ h px + h t px
dt t=h
= h px + h [−h px µx+h ]
= 1 − h µx − h (1 − h µx )µx+h
46
and:
d
3h px ≈ 2h px + h t px
dt t=2h
= 2h px + h [−2h px µx+2h ]
Note that the Euler scheme is the simplest numerical method for solving ODEs (which is
why we use it). It is also, however, among the slowest and least accurate methods. Many
better methods are available, described in any good text on numerical analysis (any maths
47
package will certainly use one of them). We would probably not use an Euler scheme in
practice.
V (0) = 0
V (n) = 0 or V (n) = 1.
Note: the direction of time is immaterial when solving ODEs. Suppose the function f (t)
satisfies the ODE:
48
f ′ (t) = g(f (t), t)
and satisfies the initial condition f (0) = c0 and the terminal condition f (T ) = cT for
some time T > 0. Then we can either:
• choose a positive step size h and advance the solution forward from f (0),or
• choose a negative step size −h and advance the solution backwards from f (T ).
In the first case, when we reach time T we should obtain the correct value f (T ) = cT (to
within numerical error) and, in the second case, when we reach time 0 we should obtain
the correct value f (0) = c0 .
In solving Thiele’s equation, we might know an initial value, but often we do not. In fact the
initial value is often the unknown quantity whose value we want to find. But we almost
always know a terminal value, because:
• a policy with no maturity benefit (e.g. a term assurance) always has policy value 0 at
expiry; and
49
• a policy with a maturity benefit (e.g. an endowment) always has policy value equal to
the maturity benefit just before expiry.
Therefore, we will solve Thiele’s equation backwards from such terminal conditions.
The following are the first few steps of an Euler scheme with step size −h for a term
assurance contract sold to a life age x, with sum assured $1 payable immediately on death
within n years and premium payable continuously at rate P̄ per annum. The policy value at
duration t is denoted V (t) as usual.
f (t) = V (t)
g(f (t), t) = V (t)δ + P̄ − µx+t (1 − V (t))
f (n) = 0.
50
d
V (n − h) ≈ V (n) − h V (t)
dt t=n
= V (n) − h[V (n)δ +
P̄ − µx+n (1 − V (n))]
and:
d
V (n − 2h) ≈ V (n − h) − h V (t)
dt t=n−h
= V (n − h) − h[V (n − h)δ +
P̄ − µx+n−h (1 − V (n − h))]
and:
51
d
V (n − 3h) ≈ V (n − 2h) − h V (t)
dt t=n−2h
= V (n − 2h) − h[V (n − 2h)δ +
P̄ − µx+n−2h (1 − V (n − 2h))]
and so on.
Premium = EPV[Benefits]
= EPV[Benefits] − EPV[Future premiums]
52
= Policy value at outset
because there are no future premiums. In other words, we can use Thiele’s equation to
compute the EPV of any benefits at all,not just policy values of contracts with regular
premiums.
Example: Consider a non-profit endowment with term 10 years sold to (30). The sum
assured of $50,000 is payable on maturity, or immediately on earlier death. The force of
mortality is µx+t and the force of interest is δ , and there are no expenses. Find the annual
rate of premium P̄ .
d
V (t) = V (t) δ + P̄ − µx+t (50, 000 − V (t)).
dt
The boundary condition is V (10) = 50, 000, but P̄ is unknown. Since this will all be
done with a computer we can find P̄ easily by trial and error.
Method 2: Set up Thiele’s equation separately for a benefit of $1 and for an annuity of $1
53
per annum. These are, respectively:
d
VA (t) = VA (t) δ + 0 − µx+t (1 − VA (t))
dt
d
Va (t) = Va (t) δ + 1 − µx+t (0 − Va (t))
dt
with boundary conditions VA (10) = 1 and Va (10) = 0.Then by the usual equivalence
principle:
54
4 Risk, Surplus and With-Profits Business
Premium and valuation bases state what future outcomes the actuary expects.But the
future is uncertain:
• Future expenses are hard to predict accurately, especially because some may be
affected by inflation.
All such sources of uncertaintyintroduce risk. The only statement that can be made with
certainty is that the future will not be exactly as assumed in the actuary’s basis.Each
introduces the possibility of a good or a bad outcome, once the future experience is known.
55
Interest: Experience > Basis
If the premium and valuation bases are the same, and the experience follows
them exactly, then the assets the office holds will always be exactly equal to
the policy value.
It follows, since we know that the experience will not exactly follow the premium/valuation
basis, that at any time the office will hold assets not equal in value to the policy value. The
56
difference is called surplusPositive surplus is good, negative surplus (a deficit) is bad.
For a portfolio of long-term contracts, the ultimate surplus cannot be known until all the
contracts have expired.But we can measure how much surplus emerges each year (or
other short period). We need to do this in order to:
because none of these can wait, possibly for decades, until the policies have expired.
Surplus is measured using the valuation basis. In the discrete model it goes as follows:
Step 1: Choose a valuation basis and calculate the policy values at the start of the year.
Step 2: Assume the office holds assets equal to the policy values at the start of the year.
Step 3: Calculate the value of the assets at the end of the year, adding interest actually earned
and premiums actually paid and deducting the actual amounts of claims and expenses.
57
Step 4: Calculate the policy values for policies in force at the end of the year.
• Step 5: The surplus emergingduring the year is the difference between (3) and (4).
In the continuous model, we measure the instantaneous rateat which surplus is emerging,
as follows:
Step 1: Choose a valuation basis and calculate the policy values at time t.
Step 2: Assume the office holds assets equal to the policy values at time t.
Step 3: By substituting the actual forces of interest and mortality (and possibly rate of
expense) into Thiele’s equation, calculate the rate at which the value of the
assets is changing.
Step 4: Using Thiele’s equation, calculate the expectedrate of change of the reserve.
Step 5: The rate at which surplus is emerging is the difference between (3) and (4).
We can measure the amount of surplus emerging over any period by integrating the rate at
which it emerges.
d
V (t) = V (t) δ + P̄x − µx+t (1 − V (t)).
dt
′
St = (δ − δ) V (t) + µx+t − µ′x+t (1 − V (t)).
Note:
• µxt − µ′x+t represents the excess of the expected mortality over the actual
experience.
Given the need to avoid negative surpluses (losses) we next consider how likely it isthat
this will happen.
60
4.2 Risk Reserves
Our starting point is a life insurance company that prices its policies using the equivalence
principle. Suppose the probability that the insured event occurs is small (e.g. a term
assurance).
Then the Li are i.i.d. random variables,and because the equivalence principle has been
61
used E[Li ] = 0.Let σ be the standard deviation of each Li , i.e. Var[Li ] = σ 2 .
The total loss on the insurance portfolio is:
N
X
L= Li
i=1
L
lim = E[L1 ].
N →∞ N
This underlies the intuitive reason for insurance to exist — pooling large numbers of
small risks leads to a more certain outcome.(The motto of the Institute of Actuaries is
certum ex incertis.)
However, the LLN does not imply that all risk can be eliminated, merely that it can be
collectivised. By the Central Limit Theorem, as N → ∞:
62
N
P
(Li − E[Li ])
i=1 2
√ ∼ Normal 0, σ
N
or:
L
√ ∼ Normal (0, 1) .
σ N
Therefore:
1
P[Loss on Portfolio] = P[L > 0] = .
2
However, all is not lost. We will show that as N increases the size of any loss is likely to be
much loweras a proportion of the premiums received. Suppose the premium per policy is
P (regular or single, it does not matter). Then the loss on the ith policy, as a proportion of
the premium, is Li /P . The total loss, as a proportion of all premiums, is L/N P .Since:
L
√ ∼ Normal(0, 1)
σ N
We have:
σ2
L σ L
= √ . √ ∼ Normal 0, 2 .
NP P N σ N P N
64
the probability of loss approaches 1/2, but the probability of a large loss approaches 0.
To use these results we need to compute σ 2 = Var[Li ].In general Var[Li ] must be
calculated numerically (easy on a spreadsheet) except in a few cases.
Li = v Kx +1 − Px äKx +1
Kx +1
Kx +1 1−v
= v − Px
d
65
Px Kx +1 Px
= 1+ v − .
d d
This means that:
2
Px Kx +1
Var[Li ] = 1+ Var[v ]
d
2
Px ∗ 2
= 1+ Ax − (Ax )
d
Example
66
• Interest: 4% p.a.
• Given A40 = 0.09422 @ 8.16% p.a.
For the ith policy:
2
P40 ∗ 2
Var[Li ] = 1+ A40 − (A40 )
d
= 0.0370
L
p ∼ Normal(0, 1).
10(0.0370)
With this distribution we can calculate approximately some relevant probabilities. We might
be interested in questions like:
To put these in perspective, note that one year’s premiums for these 10 policies is
10(0.01447) = 0.1447, so there is:
(a) a 25% chance that the future loss will exceed 283% of one year’s premiumson the
portfolio; and
68
(b) a 5% chance that the future loss will exceed 692% of one year’s premiumson the
portfolio.
Insurance depends on pooling large numbers of independent risks. But the insurer cannot
alter the fact that P[L > 0] → 1/2, it is a mathematical fact. The insurer has to find ways
69
of managing or mitigating the risk of loss.
Suppose the company holds extra assets of amount R, in addition to the reserve
equal to the policy values.This is called a risk reserve.Then instead of considering
P[L > 0], instead consider P[L − R > 0].Effectively, the risk reserve allows the insurer
to absorb losses up to R without being insolvent. Then:
(a) It is feasible for regulators to set out how big a risk reserve is needed, by specifying a
suitably small ruin probability.For example, the regulator may require that:
.
(b) The CLT shows that as the insurer sells more policies, the risk reserve needed per
policygets smaller.
Where does the risk reserve come from? The answer is it must come from capital. In fact it
is the main reason why insurance companies need capital.Capital may be provided by
investors, or by the policyholders themselves. Either way, the providers of capital
70
will expect to be rewarded.
Summary:
• For one policy, the probability of loss may be smallbut the size of the loss can be
much greaterthan the size of the premium.
• The loss as a proportion of premiums can be reducedby selling more policies BUT this
increasesthe probability of loss.
• The probability of loss can be mitigated by holding a risk reserve, available to meet
losses up to a certain limit.
• The investors who supply the capital to set up the risk reserve must be rewarded.
This is an example of a technique of risk management, which is a large and important
topic in its own right.
Next, we consider the keystone of the system which for over 200 years allowed the
policyholders themselvesto be the investors who provided the risk reserve.
71
4.3 Lidstone’s Theorem
Lidstone’s theorem states that, for whole life and endowment policies:
(i) as the rate of interest increases, net premium policy values decrease.
(ii) as the rate of mortality increases, net premium policy values increase.
This is not a trivial result since, as an example, for a whole life policy, the policy value at
time t is:
V (t) = Ax+t − Px äx+t
and both the EPVs and the net premium on the right hand side are affected by the interest
rate.
72
Proof of Lidstone’s Theorem
We will prove the ‘interest rate’ result only for the special case of a whole life policy.
Suppose δ and δ ′ represent two forces of interest (δ 6= δ ′ ) with corresponding net premium
policy values V (t)and V ′ (t)
We need to prove:
δ < δ ′ =⇒ V (t) > V ′ (t).
Now, given annual premium rates of P̄x and P̄x′ (corresponding to the forces of interest δ
and δ ′ respectively) and force of mortality µx , Thiele’s
differential equations are:
73
d
V (t) = V (t) δ + P̄x − µx+t (1 − V (t))
dt
(4.3)
d ′
V (t) = V ′ (t) δ ′ + P̄x′ − µx+t (1 − V ′ (t)).
dt
(4.4)
d ′
V (t) =V ′ (t) δ ′ + V (t) δ ′ − V (t) δ ′
(4.5) dt
+ P̄x′ − µx+t (1 − V ′ (t)).
74
d
(V (t) − V ′ (t)) = (δ ′ + µx+t ) (V (t) − V ′ (t))
(4.6) dt
− Ct
where: Ct = (P̄x′ − P̄x ) + (δ ′ − δ)V (t).Now let f (t) = V (t) − V ′ (t). Then
equation (4.6)can be written as:
d
(4.7) f (t) = (δ ′ + µx+t ) f (t) − Ct .
dt
Stage 2
d
(4.8) f (t) − (δ ′ + µx+t ) f (t) = −Ct
dt
we notice that this is a differential equation which can be solved using the integration factor
method.
76
we define the integrating factor as:
Zt
IF (t) = exp − a(s)ds .
0
d
(y(t)IF (t)) = b(t)IF (t)
dt
77
d
f (t) − (δ ′ + µx+t ) f (t) = −Ct
dt
and define the integrating factor:
Zt
IF (t) = exp − (δ ′ + µx+s )ds .
0
d
(4.9) (IF (t)f (t)) = −Ct IF (t).
dt
78
Stage 3
• f (0) = 0
• f (ω − x) = 0 for some duration ω .
79
Now integrating both sides of equation (4.9), we get:
ω−x
Z ω−x
d
Z
(IF (t)f (t)) dt = − Ct IF (t)dt
dt
0 0
80
Now, since f (ω − x) = 0 and f (0) = 0, we have:
ω−x
Z
Ct IF (t)dt = 0.
0
81
Stage 4
Given that:
Ct < 0 if t < t0
Ct ≥ 0 if t ≥ t0 .
d
Now consider (IF (t)f (t)) = −Ct IF (t):
dt
82
t < t0 =⇒ Ct < 0
=⇒ −Ct IF (t) ≥ 0
d
=⇒ (IF (t)f (t)) ≥ 0.
dt
and:
t ≥ t0 =⇒ Ct ≥ 0
=⇒ −Ct IF (t) ≤ 0
d
=⇒ (IF (t)f (t)) ≤ 0.
dt
We now have the following information on the
function IF (t)f (t):
83
(b) IF (t)f (t) = 0 when t = ω − x
d
(c) (IF (t)f (t)) ≥ 0 when t < t0
dt
d
(d) (IF (t)f (t)) ≤ 0 when t > t0 .
dt
Step 5
¿From these features we plot the graph of IF (t)f (t) against t, which must look like
Figure 3.
84
IF (t)f (t)
6
-
0 t0 ω−x t
Therefore:
86
Summary of Proof
87
4.4 With-Profits Business
• Most life insurance risks are increasingover time. If we insure risks over a long term
with a level premium, we build up a reserve.
• We can use the equivalence principleto set premiums if we insure many independent
risks (Law of Large Numbers).
• The CLT however shows that we need an additional reserve (risk reserve) to
manage or mitigatethe probability of overall loss on the insurance portfolio.
Since:
88
d
V (t) = V (t) δ + P̄ − µx+t (1 − V (t))
dt
and:
d
V (t) + St = V (t) δ ′ + P̄ − µx+t (1 − V (t))
dt
then unless the experience is bad, surplus will emerge at rate St where:
St = (δ ′ − δ) V (t).
89
• It is fair that the surplus emerging be returned to the policyholder.
• Surplus can be returned to the policyholder by declaring bonuses.
Hence we have invented with-profits business.
100 people aged exactly 50 are each sold a 15-year endowment assurance policy with
sum assured $100,000. The premiums are paid annually in advance, and the sum assured
is paid on maturity or at the end of the year of death.
Mortality: A1967–70 Ultimate, and the lives are independent with respect to mortality.
Expenses: Initial: $300. Renewal: 2.5% of each premium, including the first.
(1) State the gross future loss random variable for one policy at the outset.
90
(2) Using your answer to part (1) or otherwise, evaluate, in terms of P :
(a) the mean and variance of the loss (in present value terms) for a single policy at
outset.
(b) the mean and variance of the loss (in present value terms) for the entire portfolio at
outset.
Note: A50:15 at 12.36% per annum = 0.20426
(3) Show what values the gross annual premium P can take if the company requires that
the probability it incurs a loss (in present value terms) on the entire portfolio has to be less
than 2.5%. Use the Normal approximation.
Solution: (1)
Li = P V [Outgo] − P V [Income]
= 100K v min(K50 +1,15) + 300
− 0.975 P ämin(K
50 +1,15)
91
0.975 P
= 100K + v min(K50 +1,15)
d
0.975 P
+ 300 −
Where ∗ indicates interest at i2 + 2 i = 12.36%.
=⇒ P ≥ 4, 988.86.
94
5 Markov Multiple-State Models
Firstly, we review for single lives two equivalent model formulations. We also keep in the
background that the ultimate aim is to derive the present value of insurance payments.
There are two states, ‘alive’ and ‘dead’, and a single transition between them.
95
µad
x+t - d = Dead
a = Alive
Define t pij
s to be the probability of being in state j at age s + t, conditional on being
in state i at age s.
(ii) The probability of dying before age x + t + dt, conditional on being alive at age
x + t, is
ad
dt px+t = µad
x+t dt + o(dt).
(2) The superscript ‘ad’ on the transition intensity indicates that it refers to the transition
from the state labelled ‘a’ to the state labelled ‘d’.
(4) Assumption (ii) defines the behaviour of the model over infinitesimal time intervals dt.
The key question then is: how does this determine the model’s behaviour over extended
time intervals, e.g. years?
The answer to this key question is that Assumptions (i) and (ii) allow us to derive the the
Kolmogorov differential equationand Thiele’s differential equationand we have
already seen, in Section 3, that these can be solved numerically for all probabilities
and EPVs that we may need.
97
state occupied at age x + t:
ad ad dd aa ad
t+dt px = t px dt px+t + t px dt px+t
ad aa
= t px × 1 + t px (µx+t dt + o(dt))
Therefore:
ad
t+dt px − t pad
x o(dt)
= t paa
x µx+t + .
dt dt
d ad aa
t px = t px µx+t .
dt
Since t paa
x + t pad
x = 1, this is equivalent to:
98
d aa aa
t px = −t px µx+t
dt
The real importance of reformulating the life table model as a Markov model is that this
generalises to more complicated problems that form the basis of other insurance contracts
and problems.
Our aim in any given case is to model the life historyof a person initially age (x), of which
‘alive or dead’ is merely the simplest possible example. In general, we have a finite set of
M states S . The states in S may be labelled by numbers:
S = {1, 2, . . . , M }
99
or by letters:
S = {a, b, c, . . .}
or in any other convenient way. For each pair of distinct states i and j in S , the probability
of making a transition from state i to state j at age x + t (conditional on then being in
ij
state i) is governed by a transition intensity µx+t . This statement is given precise meaning
by making the following assumptions:
ij
(i) All intensities µx+t depend only on the current age x + t and not on any other
aspect of the life’s past history.
(iii) The probability of making any two or more transitions in time dt is o(dt).
100
5.3 More examples of Markov models
Figure 4 shows a model of a life insurance contract including the possibility that the
policyholder chooses to terminate the contract early (known as ‘withdrawal’).We have
chosen to label the states and transition intensities by numbers.
x+t
µ12 1 2 = W’draw
1 = Alive PP
P
13 PP
µx+t q 3 = Dead
P
Figure 4: Multiple decrement model: a single life subject to more than one decrement.
Figure 5 shows a model suitable for underwriting disability insurance, which replaces part
of the policyholder’s earnings while too ill to work.We have chosen to denote the
transition intensities individually by Greek letters.
101
Note that in Figure 5 the number of movements between the ‘Able’ and ‘Ill’ states is
not bounded but the model is fully specified in terms of just four intensities.This hints
at the problems we would enountered were we to attempt to specify this model in terms of
random times between transitions, i.e. the analogues of the random lifetime Tx .
σx+t
-
Able Ill
ρx+t
@
@
µx+t νx+t
@
R
@
Dead
Figure 5: Disability insurance: premiums are paid while ‘able’ and an annuity-type benefit is
payable while ‘ill’.
Figure 6 shows a restricted version of the disability insurance model, that covers only
permanent, irrecoverable illnesses.
102
σx+t -
Able Ill
@
@
µx+t νx+t
@
R
@
Dead
Figure 6: Permanent disability/Terminal Illness: This model is similar to that shown for dis-
ability insurance but only covers irrecoverable illnesses.
Figures 7 and 8 show two possible models for long-term care (LTC) insurance, which
provides for the cost of care at home or in a nursing institution in old age (usually). Claims
may be made upon the loss of a certain number of activities of daily living (ADLs)which
are essential to be able to care for oneself properly.
103
µ12
x+t -
1.Able 2.Disabled
@ µ21
x+t
µ13@
x+t µ23
x+t
@
R
@
3.Dead
Figure 7: Long-term care: This model uses the loss of activities of daily living (ADLs) as a
definition of disability and for the purposes of validating claims. ABI benchmark ADLs are:
washing, dressing, mobility, toiletting, feeding and transferring.
Note that, from a mathematical point of view, the LTC model in Figure 7 is identical to the
disability model in Figure 5. The only difference lies in the values of the intensities, which
must be parameterised using suitable data.
104
- µ14
x+t
1. Able
µ12 6
µ 21
x+t x+t
? ?
µ31
x+t
2. Mild disability µ24
x+t -
(Failure of 2 ADLs) 4. Dead
(half benefit)
µ23 6µ 32 6
x+t x+t
?
3. Disabled
(Failure of > 2 ADLs)
µ34
x+t
(full benefit)
Figure 8: Long-term care, expanded: This model is similar to the simple model of long-term
105
care, except that it allows for some benefits to be paid on partial disability (defined as the
In general, multiple state models specified in terms of intensities are important because:
106
5.4 The Kolmogorov equations: Derivation
Define the following occupancy probabilities(the first of which we have already seen).
ij
t px = P[in state j at age x + t |
in state i at age x]
ii
t px = P[in state i for agesx → x + t |
in state i at age x]
107
We have the following results for t pii
x:
ii ii
(5.10) dt px = + o(dt)
dt px
Z tX
(5.11)
ii
t px = exp − µij
x+s ds .
0 j6=i
Proof of (5.10):
If the life is in state i at age x and at age x + dt, there are just two possibilities:
(i) The life never left state i. This has probability dt pii
x by definition.
(ii) The life left state i and returned to it, which implies two or more transitions in time dt.
This has probability o(dt) by assumption (iii).
ii
dt px = dt pii
x + o(dt)
108
which is equivalent to:
ii
dt px = dt pii
x + o(dt).
Proof of (5.11):
ii ii
t+dt px = t px × dt pii
x+t
ii ii
= t px × dt px+t + o(dt)
X ij
ii
= t px × 1 − dt px+t + o(dt)
j6=i
X
= ii
t px × 1 − µij
x+t dt + o(dt) .
j6=i
109
Hence:
ii
t+dt px − dt pii
x ii
X ij o(dt)
= −t px µx+t +
dt dt
j6=i
d ii ii
X ij
t px = −t px µx+t .
dt
j6=i
This is a familiar ODE (think of the Kolmogorov equation of the ordinary life table) which
has boundary condition 0 pii
x = 1 and solution:
110
Z tX
ii
t px = exp − µij
x+s ds .
0 j6=i
111
The Kolmogorov (forward) differential equationsare a system of simultaneous
equationsfor all the probabilities t pij
x , including the case i = j .They are as follows:
d ij X ik kj ij
X jk
tp = t px µx+t − t px µx+t
dt x
k6=j k6=j
Proof:
X kj
ij ik
t+dt px = p p
t x dt x+t
k∈S
X kj jj
ik
= t px dt px+t + t pij
x dt p x+t
k6=j
X
= ik
t px (µkj
x+t dt + o(dt))
k6=j
112
X jk
ij
+ t px
1 − dt px+t
k6=j
X
= ij
t px + ik
t px (µkj
x+t dt + o(dt))
k6=j
X
− ij
t px (µjk
x+t dt + o(dt)).
k6=j
Therefore:
ij
t+dt px − t pij X X
x
= ik
t px µkj
x+t − ij
t px µjk
x+t
dt
k6=j k6=j
o(dt)
+ .
dt
Take limits as dt → 0 and:
113
d ij X ik kj ij
X jk
(5.12) t px = t px µx+t − t px µx+t
dt
k6=j k6=j
as required.
Most numerical methods of solving a single ODE can be extended to solve a system of
ODEs very simply. All that is necessary is that at each step, the solution of the entire
system of equations is advanced before going to the next step.
For example, suppose there are three states, S = {1, 2, 3}. There are therefore nine
equations of the form (5.12). Some of these may be trivial. Now suppose, for example, we
114
wish to solve these over a period of 10 years, with step size h = 0.01 years, therefore
1,000 steps in total.
d 11
The WRONGapproach is to take the first ODE, for t px , and try to advance its solution
dt
for the entire 1,000 steps, to obtain:
11 11 11
h px , 2h px , . . . , 1,000h px
before considering the other equations in the system. This will FAILbecause the other
probabilities are needed at each step.
11 12 33
h px , h px , . . . , h p x .
Then, using these values, advance the whole system one more step to obtain:
115
11 12 33
2h px , 2h px , . . . , 2h px
and so on.
For a concrete example, we use the disability model of Figure 5. This has transition
intensities labelled µx+t , νx+t , σx+t and ρx+t . It is easily shown that the Kolmogorov
equations for t p11 12
x and t px depend on each other but not on any other occupancy
probabilities (see tutorial). They are:
d 11 12
tp = t px ρx+t − t p11
x (σx+t + µx+t )
dt x
d 12 11
tp = t px σx+t − t p12
x (ρx+t + νx+t ).
dt x
We assume that the life is healthy at age x when the disability insurance policy is sold, so
the boundary conditions are 0 p11
x = 1 and 0 p12
x = 0.We use Euler’s method with step
size h.The first step is:
116
12 12 d 12
h px ≈ 0 px + h t p x
dt t=0
12 11 12
= 0 px + h 0 px · σx − 0 px · (ρx + νx )
= 0 + h [1 · σx − 0]
(5.13) = h · σx
and:
11 11 d 11
h px ≈ 0 p x + h t px
dt t=0
11 12 11
= 0 px + h 0 px · ρx − 0 px · (σx + µx )
= 1 + h [0 − 1 · (σx + µx )]
(5.14) = 1 − h(σx + µx ).
Using h p12 11
x and h px as our new boundary conditions we can perform another Euler step
117
to get approximate values of 2h p12
x and 2h p 11
x :
12 12 d 12
2h px ≈ h px + h t px
dt t=h
= h p12 11
x + h h px σx+h
−h p12
x (ρx+h + νx+h )
=h p12
x (1 − h (ρx+h + νx+h )) + h p11
x h σx+h
and
11 11 d 11
2h px ≈ h px + h t px
dt t=h
= h p11 12
x + h h p x ρx+h
−h p11
x (σx+h + µx+h )
=h p11 12
x (1 − h (µx+h + σx+h )) + h px h ρx+h
118
where h p12 11
x and h px are given by equations (5.13) and (5.14) respectively.
When we consider the reserves that need to be held for an insurance policy more general
than life insurance, e.g. disability insurance, it is clear that a different reserve needs to
be held, depending on the state currently occupied.For example, under disability
insurance:
• If the life is currently healthy, it is certainthat they are currently paying premiums and
possiblethat they might, in future, receive benefits.
• If the life is currently sick, it is certainthat they are currently receiving benefits and
possiblethat they might, in future, resume paying premiums.
119
The life office’s liability is different in each case. Define V i (t)to be the policy value, on a
given valuation basis, in respect of a life in state i ∈ S at time t.
Given a Markov model with states S , a general insurance contractis defined by
specifying the following cashflows, by analogy with a life insurance policy whose benefits
are payable immediately on death and whose premiums are payable continuously:
If, as is often the case, cashflows do not depend on t, we just write bi and bij .
120
• Possibly, expenses payable continuously at rate ei (t) per annum if in state i at time t,
or as a lump sum eij (t) on transition from state i to state j at time t. Clearly these are
analagous to the benefits bi (t) and bij (t).
These policy values are obtained as the solution of Thiele’s differential equations.We
apply exactly the same logic as for the whole life policy, by supposing the life to be in state
i at time t (i.e. age x + t) and asking, what happens in the next time dt?
(1) The reserve currently held is equal to the policy value V i (t), by definition.
(2) In time dt, interest of V i (t) δ(t) dtwill be earned by these assets.
(4) For each state j 6= i in S , a transition to state j may occur, with probability
µij
x+t dt.If it does, the following happens:
– the sum assured bij (t) is paid;
– the reserve necessary while in state j , equal to the policy value V j (t), must
121
be set up;
(Some of these may be zero, depending on the policy design.) The expected cost of a
transition into state j is therefore:
µij
x+t dt (b ij (t) + V j
(t) − V i
(t)).
V i (t + dt) − V i (t)
= V i (t) δ(t) dt − bi (t) dt
X ij
− µx+t dt (bij (t) + V j (t) − V i (t)).
j6=i
122
Divide by dt and take limits as dt → 0, and we obtain the general form of Thiele’s
equations:
d i
V (t) = V i (t) δ(t) − bi (t)
dt
X ij
− µx+t (bij (t) + V j (t) − V i (t)).
j6=i
Note that this is a system of simultaneous ODEs, one for each state i.If, as is usually
the case, benefits and force of interest do not depend on t, we get the simpler system:
d i
V (t) = V i (t) δ − bi
dt
X ij
− µx+t (bij + V j (t) − V i (t)).
j6=i
123
Note: This is not a rigorous mathematical derivation of Thiele’s equations. To give one
would require a deeper background in a certain class of stochastic processes called
counting processes.
For a concrete example, return to the disability insurance contract of Figure 5. Suppose the
premiums and benefits are defined as follows:
• Premiums at rate P̄ per annum are payable while able, i.e. b1 (t) = −P̄ .
• Sickness benefits at rate B̄ per annum are payable while sick, i.e. b2 (t) = +B̄ .
• A death benefit of S is payable immediately on death, i.e. b13 (t) = b23 (t) = S .
• The policy expires after n years.
Suppose the valuation basis is as follows:
124
Then Thiele’s differential equations are:
d 1 1
1
V (t) = V (t) δ + P̄ − µx+t S − V (t)
dt
2 1
−σx+t V (t) − V (t)
d 2 2 2
V (t) = V (t) δ − B̄ − νx+t S − V (t)
dt
1 2
−ρx+t V (t) − V (t)
d 3
V (t) = 0
dt
We will always solve Thiele’s differential equation backwards from terminal boundary
values of the V i (t).This is because these are easy to state. Suppose a policy expires at
duration n years. Then:
125
• If there is a maturity benefit (pure endowment type) of £Mi if the policy expires with
the life in state i, then V i (n) = Mi .
• If there is no maturity benefit if the policy expires with the life in state i, then
V i (n) = 0.
It would be very difficult to specify initial values V i (0) in advance.
We use an Euler scheme by analogy with Section 3.5, advancing the solution of the entire
system forward one step at a time, as we did for the Kolmogorov equations (in the other
direction).
The following are the first few steps of an Euler scheme with step size −h for the disability
insurance policy and valuation basis discussed in the last section. We note that the
boundary conditions are V i (n) = 0 for all i,and we ignore V 3 (t) since it is clearly
always zero. The first step is:
1 1 d 1
V (n − h) ≈ V (n) − h V (t)
dt t=n
126
h
= V 1 (n) − h V 1 (n) δ + P̄
1
−µx+n S − V (n)
2 1
i
−σx+n V (n) − V (n)
and:
2 2 d 2
V (n − h) ≈ V (n) − h V (t)
dt t=n
h
= V 2 (n) − h V 2 (n) δ − B̄
2
−νx+n S − V (n)
1 2
i
−ρx+n V (n) − V (n) ,
127
V 1 (n − 2h)
1 d 1
≈ V (n − h) − h V (t)
dt t=n−h
h
= V 1 (n − h) − h V 1 (n − h) δ + P̄
1
−µx+n−h S − V (n − h)
i
V 2 (n − h) − V 1 (n − h)
−σx+n−h
and:
V 2 (n − 2h)
2 d 2
≈ V (n − h) − h V (t)
dt t=n−h
h
= V 2 (n − h) − h V 2 (n − h) δ − B̄
128
2
−νx+n−h S − V (n − h)
1 2
i
−ρx+n−h V (n − h) − V (n − h) ,
and so on.
5.8 Comments
(1) The multiple state models illustrated here are all models of the life historyof a given
person, where states and transitions define the events that may be of interest. Models
of various insurance contracts are built upon these by defining the insurance
cashflows, here denoted bi (t) and bij (t), and interest and expenses, but these are
not themselves part of the underlying life history models.
(2) The Markov assumption was essential in the above development. In particular we used
it when we assumed we could define policy values V i (t) that depended on the
129
state occupied at time t and nothing else.
130
6 Insurances on Joint Lives
6.1 Introduction
It is common for life insurance policies and annuities to depend on the death or survival of
more than one life. For example:
(i) A policy which pays a monthly benefit to a wife or other dependents after the death of
the husband (widow’s or dependent’s pension).
(ii) A policy which pays a lump-sum on the second death of a couple (often to meet
inheritance tax liability).
We will confine attention to policies involving two livesbut the same approaches can be
extended to any number of lives. We assume that policies are sold to a life age x and a life
age y , denoted (x) and (y).
• Assurances paying out on first death, and annuities payable until first death.
131
• Assurances paying out on second death, and annuities payable until second death.
• Assurances and annuities whose payment depends on the order of deaths.
The following multiple-state model represents the joint mortality of two lives, (x) and (y).
State 1 µ12
t State 2
(x) Alive - (x) Dead
(y) Alive (y) Alive
µ13
t µ24
t
? ?
State 3 State 4
(x) Alive µ34
t (x) Dead
-
(y) Dead (y) Dead
132
Notes:
• We just index the transition intensities by time t. Other notations are possible.
• We implicitly assume that the simultaneous death of (x) and (y) is impossible: there
is no direct transition from state 1 to state 4.
Here we list the main EPVs met in practice, giving their symbols in the standard actuarial
notation. In the first place, we assume all insurance contracts (assurance- or annuity-type)
to be for all of lifeand to be of unit amount, i.e. $1 sum assured or $1 annuity per
annum.
Joint-life assurances
• Āxy is the EPV of $1 paid immediately on the first death of (x) or (y).
• Āxy is the EPV of $1 paid immediately on the second death of (x) and (y).
133
Contingent assurances
• Ā1xy is the EPV of $1 paid immediately on the death of (x)provided (y) is then alive,
i.e. provided (x) is the first to die.
• Āxy1 is the EPV of $1 paid immediately on the death of (y)provided (x) is then alive,
i.e. provided (y) is the first to die.
• Ā2xy is the EPV of $1 paid immediately on the death of (x)provided (y) is then dead,
i.e. provided (x) is the second to die.
• Āxy2 is the EPV of $1 paid immediately on the death of (y)provided (x) is then dead,
i.e. provided (y) is the second to die.
Joint-life annuities
• āxy is the EPV of an annuity of $1 per annum, payable continuously, until the first of
(x) or (y) dies.
134
• āxy is the EPV of an annuity of $1 per annum, payable continuously, until the second
of (x) or (y) dies.
Reversionary annuities
• āx|y is the EPV of an annuity of $1 per annum, payable continuously, to (y) as long as
(y) is alive and (x) is dead.
• āy|x is the EPV of an annuity of $1 per annum, payable continuously, to (x) as long as
(x) is alive and (y) is dead.
The notation for reversionary annuities helpfully suggests (taking āx|y as an example) an
annuity payable to (y) deferred until (x) is dead. Think of m |ān from Financial
Mathematics.
135
Limited terms
The above contracts may all be written for a limited term of n years, in which case the
usual n is appended to the subscript.
Evaluation of EPVs
In the multiple-state, continuous-time model, we can compute all the above EPVs simply by
appropriate choices of assurance benefits bij or annuity benefits bi in Thiele’s
differential equations. The following table lists these choices for whole-life contracts.
136
EPV b1 b2 b3 b12 b13 b24 b34
Āxy 0 0 0 1 1 0 0
Āxy 0 0 0 0 0 1 1
Ā1xy 0 0 0 1 0 0 0
Āxy1 0 0 0 0 1 0 0
Āxy2 0 0 0 0 0 1 0
Ā2xy 0 0 0 0 0 0 1
āxy 1 0 0 0 0 0 0
āx|y 0 1 0 0 0 0 0
āy|x 0 0 1 0 0 0 0
āxy 1 1 1 0 0 0 0
137
d 1
V (t) = V 1 (t) δ − (µ12
t + µ13
t )(1 − V 1
(t))
dt
d 2 d 3 d
V (t) = V (t) = V 4 (t) = 0
dt dt dt
Composite benefits
Many joint life contracts can be built up out of the above EPVs and the EPVs of single life
benefits. This is generally the simplest way to compute them, especially if using tables
rather than a spreadsheet.
Example: Consider a pension of $10,000 per annum, payable continuously as long as (x)
and (y) are alive, reducing by half on the death of (x) if (x) dies before (y). (This would
be a typical retirement pension with a spouse’s benefit.)Its EPV, denoted ā say, is most
easily computed by noting that $10,000 p.a. is payable as long as (x) is alive, and in
138
addition, $5,000 p.a. is payable if (y) is alive but (x) is dead, hence:
By similar reasoning, an annuity of $1 p.a. payable to (y) for life can be decomposed into
an annuity of $1 p.a. payable until the first death of (x) and (y), plus a reversionary
annuity of $1 p.a. payable to (y) after the prior death of (x); hence the useful:
The one type of joint life benefit whose EPV is not easily written in terms of first-death,
second-death and single-life EPVs is the contingent assurance. We defer discussion until
139
Section 6.4.
It is also possible to specify a joint lives model via random future lifetimes. We have the
random variables:
Tmin is the random time until the first death occurs, and Tmax is the random time until the
140
second death occurs.
Define:
141
and (useful result) the joint life survival function t pxy is the product of the single life
survival functions.
t qxy = 1 − t pxy
= 1 − t px t p y
= 1 − {(1 − t qx )(1 − t qy )}
= t qx + t q y − t qx t qy .
Solution:
n qxy = n qx + n qy − n qx n qy
142
= 0.2 + 0.4 − 0.2 × 0.4
= 0.52
n pxy = n px × n py
= 0.8 × 0.6
= 0.48
To simplify the evaluation of probabilities, like t pxy , we can develop a life table function,
lxy , associated with Tmin .
If Tx and Ty are independent then:
143
We obtain the p.d.f. of Tmin , denoted fxy (t), by differentiation when Tx and Ty are
independent:
d
fxy (t) = t qxy
dt
d
= − t pxy
dt
d
= − t px · t py
dt
d d
= − t px t py + t p y t p x
dt dt
144
Compare this to the single life case:
fx (t) = t px µx+t .
Now, define µxy (t) as the ‘force of mortality’ associated with Tmin . We can show directly
that
fxy (t)
µxy (t) = = µx+t + µy+t .
p
t xy
However, using the multiple-state formulation of the model, we see that Tmin is just the
145
time when state 1 is left.The survival function associated with this event is, by definition,
11
t p• (where the bullet represents policy inception) and we know that:
Z t
11
t p• = exp − µ12 13
s + µs ds .
0
By differentiating this, the ‘force of mortality’ associated with leaving state 1 is the sum of
the intensities out of state 1 without assuming that Tx and Ty are independent.
Define:
146
t pxy = P{Tmax > t)}
= P{Tx > t or Ty > t}
= P{Tx > t} + P{Ty > t}
− P{Tx > t and Ty > t}
= t px + t py − t pxy
which does not require Tx and Ty to be independent. If they are independent then:
t pxy = t px + t p y − t px t p y
and also:
t qxy = P{Tmax ≤ t}
147
= P {Tx ≤ t and Ty ≤ t}
= P{Tx ≤ t}P{Ty ≤ t} = t qx t qy .
The p.d.f. of Tmax and the ‘force of mortality’ µxy (t)associated with Tmax are left as
tutorial questions.
Define:
◦ ◦
exy = E[Tmin ] and exy = E[Tmax ].
148
These can be verified by considering the three exhaustive and exclusive cases:
149
Evaluation of EPVs
We can evaluate EPVs using the distributions of Tmin and Tmax , just as for a single life,
as an alternative to solving Thiele’s equations. For example, consider an assurance with a
sum assured of $1 payable immediately on the first death of (x) and (y).
Note that evaluating an integral numerically is not significantly easier than solving Thiele’s
equations numerically.
150
6.4 Curtate Future Joint Lifetimes
Basic definitions
exy = E [Kmin ]
exy = E [Kmax ] .
151
Kmin and Kmax are given by:
k qxy
= P {k ≤ Tmin < k + 1}
= P {Kmin = k}
k qxy
= P {k ≤ Tmax < k + 1}
= P {Kmax = k} .
Example: Given:
non-smoker 70 − x + t
t qx =
80 − x
valid for 0 ≤ x ≤ 70 and 0 ≤ t ≤ 10, and that the force of mortality for smokers is twice
that for non-smokers, calculate the expected time to first death of a (70) smoker and a (70)
non-smoker. You are given that the lives are independent.
152
Solution: We want:
Z 10 Z 10
◦ s n−s s n−s s n−s
e70:70 = t p70:70 dt = t p70 t p70 dt.
0 0
Now let µx be the force of mortality for non-smokers, then:
Z t
s
t px = exp − 2 µx+r dr
0
Z t 2
= exp − µx+r dr
0
n−s 2
= t px
2
10 − t
= .
10
Since:
n−s 70 − 70 + t 10 − t
t px =1− =
80 − 70 10
153
therefore:
Z 10 3
◦ s n−s 10 − t
e70:70 = dt = 2.5 years.
0 10
Any annuity or assurance we can define as a function of the single lifetime Kx , we can
define using Kmin , therefore depending on the first deathor Kmax , therefore
depending on the second death.
PV = äK .
min +1
154
We denote the EPV of this benefit äxy so:
äxy = E[äKmin +1 ]
∞
X
= äk+1 k qxy
k=0
X∞
= v k k pxy
k=0
Since the distribution of the present value is known, the variance, Var[äKmin +1 ], and
other moments can be calculated.
PV = äK .
max +1
155
We denote the EPV of this benefit äxy so:
äxy = E[äKmax +1 ]
∞
X
= äk+1 k qxy
k=0
X∞
= v k k pxy .
k=0
156
∞
X ∞
X ∞
X
= v k k px + v k k py − v k k pxy
k=0 k=0 k=0
= äx + äy − äxy .
Hence also:
äxy + äxy = äx + äy .
157
e.g. a(55) tables, but note that the values of axy are given not äxy , and they are only
given for even ages — may need to use linear interpolation.
For example:
1
a66:61 ≈ (a66:60 + a66:62 ).
2
(ii) Given commutation functions. e.g. A1967–70 tables, but note that they are only given
for x = y and at 4% interest.
Note that (assuming independence):
∞
X ∞
X
äxy = v t t pxy = v t t p x t py
t=0 t=0
∞
t lx+t ly+t
X
= v
t=0
lx ly
158
∞
( 1
)
X v 2 (x+y)+t lx+t ly+t
= 1
t=0 v 2 (x+y) lx ly
Nxy
=
Dxy
where:
1
Dxy = v 2 (x+y)
lx ly
X∞
Nx+t:y+t = Dx+t+r: y+t+r .
r=0
159
Warning:
äxy:n = äxy − n äxy
= äxy − v n n px n py äx+n:y+n
1 Dx+n Dy+n
= äxy − n äx+n:y+n .
v Dx Dy
(i) ä80:75
(ii) 10 | ä70:65 .
Solution:
We can extend many of the formulations for single life annuities to joint life annuities. This
applies to:
A certain life office issues a last survivor annuity of $2,000 per annum, payable annually in
arrear, to a man aged 68 and a woman aged 65.
(a) Using the a(55) ultimate table (male/female as appropriate) and a rate of interest of
4% per annum, estimate the expected present value of this benefit.
(b) Using the basis of (a) above, derive an expression (which you need NOT evaluate)
162
for the standard deviation of the present value of this benefit, in terms of single life
and joint life annuity functions.
Solution:
163
(b) Present Value = 2000 aK
max
h i
So we want: Var 2000 aK
max
h i
= 20002 Var äK −1
max +1
h i
= 20002 Var äK
max +1
Kmax +1
2 1−v
= 2000 Var
d
2
2000 K
max +1
= Var v
d
2 2
2000 ∗ m f
= A68:65 − Am f
68:65
d
164
where * means evaluated at:
j = i2 + 2i = 8.16%.
We now use:
Axy = 1 − d äxy
and:
äxy = äx + äy − äxy
and:
p
SD[P V ] = V ar[P V ]
to get: (
2000
∗ ∗ m ∗ f ∗ m f
1− d ä68 + ä65 − ä68:65
d
h i2 12
f m f
− 1 − d äm
68 + ä65 − ä68:65 .
165
Joint life assurances
Consider an assurance with sum assured $1, payable at the end of the year of death of the
first of (x) and (y ) to die. The benefit is payable at time Kmin + 1 so has present value:
v Kmin +1 .
Ax = 1 − däx .
166
It can be shown by similar reasoning that:
Axy = 1 − däxy
Āxy = 1 − δ āxy
Axy:n = 1 − däxy:n
Āxy:n = 1 − δ āxy:n
and so on.
167
and similar relationships can be derived, e.g:
Axy = 1 − däxy
Axy:n = 1 − däxy:n .
Reversionary Annuities
just by noticing that the following define identical cashflows no matter when (x) and (y )
should die:
(1) a reversionary annuity of $1 per annum payable continuously while (y) is alive,
following the death of (x).
(2) an annuity of $1 per annum payable continuously to (y) for life, less an annuity of $1
168
per annum payable continuously until the first death of (x) and (y).
Hence the cashflows have identical present values, and the same EPVs. We can apply
similar reasoning to other variants of reversionary annuities, for example:
∞
1 X k
= v m k py (1 − k px )
m m m
k=0
169
(m)
ax|y = a(m)
y − a(m)
xy
∞
1 X k
= v m k py (1 − k px ).
m m m
k=1
For example:
Hence:
äx|y = ax|y .
170
(a) äx|y ≈ āx|y
(m)
(b) äx|y ≈ äx|y .
Example: Calculate the annual premium (payable while both lives are alive) for the
following contract for a man aged 70 and woman aged 64.
Benefits:
Basis:
= 0.9 P äm f
70:64
= 0.9 P (1 + 5.576)
= 5.9184 P.
EPV of assurance
= 10, 000Ām f
70:64
m f
= 10, 000 1 − δ ā70:64
≈ 10, 000 1 − 0.076961(am f
70:64 + 0.5)
172
EPV of reversionary annuity
= 5, 000 ām f
70|64 + āf64|70
m
= 5, 000 am f
70|64 + af m
64|70
f m f f m
= 5, 000 a64 − a70:64 + am
70 − a64:70
173
Contingent assurances
Consider a contingent assurance with sum assured $1 payable immediately on the death
of (x), if (y ) is still then alive.
The probability that life (x) dies within t years with life (y ) being alive when life (x) dies is
1
denoted t qxy and:
1
t qxy = P[(x) dies within t years and before (y)]
= P[Tx < t and Tx < Ty ].
This is an example of a contingent probability,so called because they are associated with
the death of a life contingent on the survival or death of another life.
Now let fx (r) be the density of Tx and fy (r) be the density of Ty , then:
Z t Z ∞
1
t qxy = fx (r)fy (s)ds dr
r=0 s=r
174
Z t Z ∞
= fx (r) fy (s)ds dr.
r=0 s=r
Since: Z ∞
fy (s)ds = r py
s=r
then: Z t
1
t qxy = r px µx+r r py dr.
r=0
Illustration:(x) survives to time r and then dies and (y) survives beyond r, giving:
r px µx+r r py
?
(x) survives = r px (y) survives = r py
| -
z }| {
| | -
Age x x+r
y 175y + r
Note that since one of (x) and (y) has to die first:
1
t qxy + t qxy1 = t qxy .
2
We define t qxy as the probability that (x) dies within t years but after (y) has died.
Therefore:
1 2
t qx = t qxy + t qxy
from which: Z t
2
t qxy = r px µx+r (1 − r py ) dr.
0
176
¿From this it can be shown that:
Z ∞
Ā1xy = v r r px µx+r r py dr.
0
Similarly, we can derive an expression for the EPV of a benefit of $1 payable immediately
on the death of (x) if it is after that of (y), denoted Ā2xy :
Z ∞
Ā2xy = v r r px µx+r (1 − r py ) dr.
0
If the two lives are the same age, and the same mortality table is applies to both, then:
1
Ā1xx = Āxx
2
1
A1xx = Axx
2
1
Ā2xx = Āxx
2
1
A2xx = Axx .
2
178
6.5 Examples
Example 1
Find the expected present value of an annuity of $10,000 p.a. payable annually in advance
to a man aged 65, reducing to $5,000 p.a. continuing in payment to his wife, now aged 61,
if she survives him.
Basis:
EPV
m f
= 10, 000 äm
65 + 5, 000 ä65|61
m f
= 10, 000 (am
65 + 1) + 5, 000 a65|61
179
= 10, 000 (7.4 + 1) + 5, 000 af61 − am f
65:61
Since:
1 m f
am f
65:61 ≈ a m f m f m f
+ a66:60 + a64:62 + a64:60
4 66:62
1
= (6.392 + 6.519 + 6.709 + 6.854)
4
= 6.619.
Example 2
2
(a) Express n qxy in terms of single life probabilities and contingent probabilities
referring to the first death.
1
(b) Suppose µx = 80−x for 0 ≤ x ≤ 80,
180
2
evaluate 20 q40:50 .
Solution
(a) t qxy2
Z t
= r py µy+r (1 − r px ) dr
r=0
Z t Z t
= r py µy+r dr − r py µy+r r px dr
r=0 r=0
= t qy − t qxy1 .
(b) n qx = 1 − n px
Z n
= 1 − exp − µx+t dt
0
181
Z n
1
= 1 − exp − dt
0 80 − x − t
n
= 1 − exp {[log (80 − x − t)]0 }
80 − x − n
= 1 − exp log
80 − x
n
= .
80 − x
182
2 1
∴ 20 q40:50 = 20 q50 − 20 q40:50
20 20 × 40 − 12 202
= −
30 40 × 30
1
= .
6
Example 3
Consider a reversionary annuity of $1 p.a. payable quarterly in advance during the lifetime
of (y) following the death of (x). Show that the expected present value of this benefit is
approximately equal to:
1 1
ax|y + Āxy .
8
Solution
183
(x) dies = µx+t
?
(x) survives = t px (y) survives = t py
| -
(4)
z }| { and gets äy+t
| | -
Age x x+t
y y+t
Hence:
Z ∞
(4)
EPV = v t t px µx+t t py äy+t dt
0
Z ∞
t 1
≈ v t px µx+t t py āy+t + dt
0 8
Z ∞
= v t t px µx+t t py āy+t dt
0
184
Z ∞
1
+ v t t px µx+t t py dt
8 0
1 1 1 1
= āx|y + Āxy ≈ ax|y + Āxy .
8 8
185
7 Policy Design and Duration Dependence
7.1 Introduction
In this section, we look in more detail at features of disability insurance and long-term care
insurance. We will find that this introduces duration dependence of two forms:
(1) Some of the transition intensities may depend on the length of time (duration) spent
in a state.In the case the Markov assumption does not hold.
(2) Some of the policy cashflowsmay depend on the duration spent in a state. This can
happen even if the underlying life-history model is Markov.
Disability insurance is commonly called Income Protection Insurance (IPI) in the UK. It
used to be known as Permanent Health Insurance (PHI) but this is obsolete. It is meant to
186
pay a benefit in the form of income during periods of incapacity due to sickness and
disability.
The history of IPI goes back to friendly societies (FSs) in the late 19th and early 20th
centuries. This preceded the welfare state period and FSs provided small scale sickness
and unemployment benefits, life assurance, funeral costs, etc., often in local communities.
FSs still exist as small scale insurance companies.
In the mid 20th century the welfare state began to provide modest benefits in the event of
sickness or permanent disability, so FSs were no longer so necessary as a ‘safety net’.
However, there is still a need for sickness benefits for better paid workers. IPI is currently
issued by many mainstream insurers.
In the last section we just assumed that premiums were payable continuously while able,
benefits were payable continuously while sick, and death benefits might be paid as well. In
practice, IPI policies are more complicated.
Term: The policies are typically written up to the normal retirement age (NRA).
Definition of sickness: The policy will specify the definition of sickness. A typical
187
definition is:
“totally unable, through sickness or accident, to follow own occupation
and not following any other for profit or reward.”
Note that a definition like “unable to
follow any occupation” may be very
restrictive to the policyholder.
Exclusions: There may be exclusions to inability to work due to pregnancy, AIDS, drug
related illnesses etc.
Benefits: Benefits are usually in the form of a monthly (or weekly) income.This may be
fixed, or increase with inflation, or it may fall to a lower level (e.g. half) after some fixed
duration of payment, to encourage the policyholder to return to work.
Waiver of Premiums: Since premiums are not paid while the benefit is received, this is
188
also a benefit of waiver of premiums.
Deferred Period: Benefits do not, in fact, start as soon as the policyholder falls sick. They
are deferred for a period of time, chosen by the policyholder, during which the
policyholder must remain sick, or benefits will not commence. This is called the
deferred period.We denote it d (in years). Typical values are 1 week, 4 weeks, 13
weeks, 26 weeks or 52 weeks, i.e. d ≈ 1/52, 1/12, 1/4, 1/2 or 1 year.
Waiting period: A period of time after taking out a IPI policy, during which the new
policyholder is not entitled to sickness benefits.This may be 6 months. It is not the
same as the deferred period.
Off-Period: If the benefits are cut after some duration of continuous sickness (see above),
the off-period defines the minimum period of good health that must pass before
two
episodes of sickness can be considered as different.
Benefit Limits: The benefit will be reduced if the policyholder’s total net income is greater
than, say, 75% of net income before sickness. This removes the chance that a
189
policyholder will be better off sick than at work.
Underwriting: Medical underwriting is similar to, but not the same as, life insurance. In
particular, more details about occupation are considered for IPI underwriting than
for life insurance underwriting.
zHealthy
}| { Healthy
z }| {
Status Sick
|
Healthy
|
Sick
| | | -|
Age x d- d - N RA
B
Insurance | Premiums -
| | Premiums -|
-
Payments
190
• There is greater scope for moral hazard than in life insurance and hence the need for
greater claims control.
• Policies are expensive and the need for IPI may not be clear and so they may not be
easy to sell.
Occupancy probabilities
By definition, the deferred period means that the payment of sickness benefit depends on
the duration of sickness. This is true even if the underlying life history model is
Markov.Therefore we define:
12
d,t px = P[ life is sick at age x + t with duration
of sickness ≤ d | life is healthy at age x ]
191
Since only the policy cashflows while sick are affected, we do not need to define similar
probabilities for any other states.
To find an expression for this in terms of more basic quantities, we consider the last time
at which the policyholder fell sick.This could have been any time between time t − d
and t. There are two cases:
Case 1: d ≥ t. Since we knew anyway that the life last fell sick between time 0 and time t,
knowing that the duration of sickness is ≤ d gives us no additional information, so:
12
d,t px = t p12
x .
Case 2: d < t. The event (x) fell sick for the last time at time s ≤ drequires (x) to be
healthy at age x + s, to fall sick before age x + s + ds, and then to remain sick for
suration t − s. See the following diagram:
192
fall sick at time s = σx+s
Healthy at ?
remain sick = t−s p22
time s = s p11
x | - x+s
z }| {
| | | | -
Time 0 t−d s t
d -
This event has probability: t−d≤s≤t
11
s px σx+s ds t−s p22
x+s
Zt
12 11
d,t px = s px σx+s t−s p22
x+s ds.
s=t−d
193
This can be evaluated by numerical integration.
EPVs
When benefits are duration-dependent, Thiele’s equations do not hold. However, it is still
possible to calculate premiums and reserves in various ways, although we lose the
extreme generality and flexibility that Thiele’s equations give us.
We show here one way to calculate IPI premiums when the policy has a deferred
period.It is by analogy with the EPV of a life annuity, payable continuously, which is:
Z ∞
EP V = āx = v t t px dt.
0
This has the following interpretation: the annuity dt is payable at time t if the statusof
being alive is fulfilled. This has probability t px and payment at time t is discounted by v t .
194
Now apply the same reasoning to the following IPI policy issued to a healthy life aged x.
• sickness benefit is payable continuously at rate B̄ per annum while the life is sick with
duration greater than d years.
Premiums are payable at time t as long as the status ‘alive and not sick for longer than
d years’is fulfilled, which has probability t p11
x + 12
d,t px .
Benefits are payable at time t as long as the status ‘alive and sick for longer than d
years’is fulfilled, which has probability t p12
x − 12
d,t px .
Summing (integrating) the discounted cashflows over the policy term we have:
195
Zn
t 11 12
P̄ v t px + d,t px dt =
t=0
Zn
t 12 12
B̄ v t px − d,t px dt
t=0
from which P̄ can be found. A similar approach can be used in many cases.
Example: Faculty and Institute of Actuaries: Subject 105 April 2002: Question 10.
The following 3 state model is used to price various sickness policies. The forces of
transition σ , ρ, µ and ν depend only on age.
196
ρx
State H
State S
Healthy - Sick
σx
@
@ µx νx
@R
@
State D
Dead
Using these probabilities and/or forces of transition, write down an expression for the
expected present value of each of the following sickness benefits for a life currently aged
197
35 and healthy. The constant force of interest is δ .
(a) $1,000 per annum payable continuously while sick, but all benefits cease at age 65
(b) $1,000 per annum payable continuously while in the sick state for any continuous
period in excess of a year. However, any benefit period is limited to 5 years
payments, but the number of possible benefit periods is unlimited
(c) $1,000 per annum payable continuously throughout the first period of sickness only
Solution:
(a)
Z 30
−δ t HS
EPV = 1, 000 e t p35 dt
0
(b)
Z ∞ Z 6
−δ t HS
EPV = 1, 000 e t p35,z dz dt
0 1
198
Z ∞ Z 6
−δ t HH −δ r SS
or 1, 000 e t p35 σ35+t e r p35+t dr dt
0 1
(c)
Z ∞ Z ∞
−δ t HH −δ r SS
EPV = 1, 000 e t p35 σ35+t e r p35+t dr dt
Z 0∞ 0
−δ t HH
or 1, 000 e t p35 σ35+t
Z0 ∞
× ār r pSS
35+t (ρ35+t+r + ν35+t+r ) dr dt
0
There is strong evidence that the intensities of transitions out of the ill
statedepend on how long a life has been illas well as on age.
A multiple-state model in which any intensity depends on the duration of
199
stay in a state is called a semi-Markov model.
UK Actuarial
Profession
Organisation/
Funding/
?
personnel
Insurance data -
Report on CMIB
Companies
each Co’s CMIB re-
experience ?
ports/
Standard
200
Tables
The CMIB collects and analyses data from many UK life offices for the
following classes of business:
• Life insurance
• Critical illness insurance
• Income protection insurance.
For IPI, the CMIB receives about 2/3 of all UK data.To indicate the volume
of data involved, Table 2 shows the numbers of claim inceptionsand
recoveriesreported in 1987–94, males and females combined. (There are
fewer recoveries than claim inceptions because: (a) sickness can be
terminated by other reasons like death;and (b) during a period on
expanding new business new claims will exceed recoveries.
201
Table 2: Numbers of events in CMIB IPI data 1987–94.
Claim
D1 30,311 12,409
D4 5,707 3,660
202
We now focus on data for males from 1975–87, which have been reported
at great length (Source: CMI Report No.12 (1991).
203
Table 3: Sample mortality values from different tables.
Sickness Age
Mortality Duration 30 50
204
Mortality from sick, νx :
There was very little data. For comparison we consider some sample
intensities in Table 3 and note the following:
• Mortality from sick increases with duration (up to about 15 weeks), then
decreases and finally increases (not shown).
205
Table 4: Sample values for ‘sickness’ transition intensities.)
x D1 D26
30 0.326 0.113
45 0.266 0.100
60 0.300 0.131
We note that:
• For both D1 and D26, the sickness intensities σx do not change much
with age.This is slightly odd: is it realistic that a 60-year old is
equally likely to fall sick in a short time interval as a 30-year old?
206
• The sickness intensities at D1 are roughly 3 times the intensities at
D26.
Claim inceptions:
We note that while the model is specified in terms of sickness intensities,
the CMIB is only able to observe claim inceptions,which are not the same
thing because of the deferred period.
Consider a healthy life age x with an IPI policy with deferred period d years.
Any episode of episode of duration less than d years will not lead to a
claim inception.
Given that to make a claim a life must first fall sick and then remain sick for
duration d, claim inception intensities at age x + t + d should be given by:
σx+t d p22
x+t .
207
Sample values are given in Table 5.
Deferred Period
Age D1 D26
30 0.126 0.00041
45 0.127 0.00146
60 0.173 0.00793
208
Sample values of the recovery intensities (same for all deferred periods) are
shown in Table 6.
Age at Onset
Duration 30 50
209
We note the following:
• Recovery rates change more quickly with duration, z , than with age
x.This adds to the strong evidence for duration-dependence.
• The rapid change of recovery rates with duration will force us to use a
small step size for numerical calculations.The CMIB used 1/3 week.
210
Table 7: Comparison of ‘Actual/Expected’ ratio over time.
Males Females
We note that:
• Male and female recovery experience is similar but claims for females
are much higher.
212
Table 8: Comparison of ‘Actual/Expected’ ratio between companies.
Claims Recoveries
Company % %
A 82 73
B 64 58
C 91 72
D 102 61
E 58 46
213
Company E has low numbers of claims but low recovery rates
• underwriting procedures
• target market
• claims control.
All the evidence of the last section points to transition intensities out of the
sick state that depens on duration as well as age. That is, the model in
Figure 9, where:
214
x represents age at policy inception
1 σx+t -
2 Sick
Healthy ρx+t,z
@
µx+t@ νx+t,z
@
R
@
3 Dead
216
algorithms.
(d) Convenient (tabulated/ computer package)
functions to calculate premiums and reserves.
gh
t px,z = P[ life is in state h at age x + t | life is
in state g at age x with duration z]
gh
d,t x,z = P[ life is in state h at age x + t with
p
duration ≤ d | life is in state g
217
at age x with duration z ]
gg
p
t x,z = P[ life stays in state g from x → x + t |
life is in state g
at age x with duration z ].
Notes:
• t pgh
x,z = ∞,t p gh
x,z = t+z,t p gh
x,z
• if g = 2 and z = 0 we write:
21 22 22
t px , d,t px , t px .
218
Deriving t p11
x and t p 22
x,z
(a) The transition intensities out of the healthy state are identical to those
for the Markov model. Hence we have the same results:
d 11 11
p
t x = −t x (σx+t + µx+t )
p
dt
Zt
11
t px = exp − (σx+r + µx+r )dr .
0
219
22
t+dt px,z = t p22
x,z × dt p 22
x+t,z+t
Zt
22
t px,z = exp − (ρx+r,z+r + νx+r,z+r )dr.
0
Deriving t p11
x
220
State occupied
Route 1 1 1 1
Route 2 1 2 1
| | | | -
Age x x + ux + t x + t + dt
Period length| t -| dt -|
Where time u represents the final time a life falls sick before age x + t,in
case they are sick at age x + t (Route 2).
221
• a life healthy at x + t and sick at
x + t + dt must have made exactly one movement.
However, t is an extended period, unlike dt. Therefore:
11
t+dt x = P[ life is healthy at x + t ]
p
222
× P[ life stays healthy in x + t
→ x + t + dt]
+ P[life is sick at x + t ]
× P[life recovers in x + t
→ x + t + dt]
11
= p
t x [1 − (µx+t + σx+t ) dt + o(dt)]
Zt
+ u p11x σ · p 22
x+u t−u x+u ρx+t,t−u du dt
0
+ o(dt).
Rearranging:
223
11
t+dt px − t p11
x
dt
= −t p11
x (µx+t + σx+t )
Zt
11
+ u px σx+u · t−u p22
x+u ρx+t,t−u du
0
o(dt)
+
dt
and on letting dt → 0 we get the differential
equation:
d 11 11
p
t x = − p
t x (µx+t + σx+t )
dt
224
Zt
11 22
+ p
u x σx+u t−u x+u ρx+t,t−u du.
· p
0
Reminder:
12
w,t px = P[ life is sick at age x + t with
duration ≤ w | healthy at age x ].
d 12
Now consider w,t px under two cases:
dw
(i) If w ≥ t, then:
12 12
p
w,t x = p
t x
225
and so does not depend on w . Hence:
d 12
w,t px = 0 if w ≥ t.
dw
(ii) If w < t, then the duration of sickness is less than the time interval t.
Therefore, the sickness has to start between ages:
x + t − w and x + t.
To derive the differential equation we introduce a small interval of time
dwsuch that:
0 < dw < t − w.
So, we have:
0 ≤ w < w + dw < t
226
and we consider the probability:
12
w+dw,t px .
sickness begins
State occupied z }| {
Route 1 1 1 1 2
Route 2 1 1 2 2
| | | |-
Age x x+t x+t x+t
−w − dw −w
Period length| -| -| -|
t − w − dw dw w
Remembering that dw is the only interval we are defining as short, we have:
12
w+dw,t px
227
= P[ sick at age x + t with
duration ≤ w + dw | healthy at age x]
12
= w,t px
11
+ t−w−dw px[σx+t−w−dw dw + o(dw)]
22
×(w px+t−w + o(dw)) .
Rearranging gives:
228
12 12
p
w+dw,t x − p
w,t x
dw
11 22 o(dw)
= t−w−dw px · σx+t−w−dw · w px+t−w +
dw
and taking limits as dw → 0, we get:
d 12 11 22
p
w,t x = p
t−w x · σ · p
x+t−w w x+t−w .
dw
Therefore:
229
11 22
t−w p x σx+t−w · w p x+t−w 0 ≤ w < t
d 12
w,t x =
p
dw
0 w ≥ t.
For more formulae see Tutorial.
Recall that:
230
Zt
11
p
t x = exp − (σx+r + µx+r )dr
0
Zt
22
p
t x,z = exp
− (ρx+r,z+r + νx+r,z+r )dr .
0
Recall that:
d 11
t px = −t p11
x (µx+t + σx+t )
dt
231
Zt
11
+ u px σx+u · t−u p22
x+u ρx+t,t−u du.
0
11
0 px =1
and we choose a step size, h(the CMIB used stepsize 1/156 year).
232
By noting that:
d 11
t px = −0 p11
x (µx + σx )
dt t=0
Z0
11
+ u px σx+u · t−u p22
x+u ρx,−u du
0
= − (µx + σx )
we have:
11
h px = 1 − h · (µx + σx ) .
d 11
t px = −h p11
x (µx+h + σx+h )
dt t=h
Zh
11
+ u px σx+u · h−u p22
x+u ρx+h,h−u du
0
and so on.
12 11
p
s,s x = 0,s x σx+s s
p
234
12 11
s,2s px = 0,2s px σx+2s s
12 12 11 22
p
2s,2s x = p
s,2s x + p
s x σ s p
x+s s x+s
Determining EPVs
65−x
Z
t 11 12
P v p
t x + p
d,t x dt =
t=0
236
65−x
Z
t 12 12
B̄ v t,t px − d,t px dt
t=0
0 for duration ≤ d1
B̄1 for d1 < duration ≤ d1 + d2
B̄2 for duration ≥ d1 + d2
with premiums waived while any benefit is payable. The equation of value is
then:
237
65−x
Z
t 11 12
P̄ v p
t x + p
d1 ,t x dt
t=0
65−x
Z
t 12 12
= B̄1 v d1 +d2 ,t px − d1 ,t px dt
t=0
65−x
Z
t 12 12
+ B̄2 v t,t px − d1 +d2 ,t px dt.
t=0
238
7.6 Long-term care insurance
Background
Long-term care is care provided to those people who are no longer able to
look after themselves, typically the elderly or infirm.
LTC can:
It has been estimated that the demand for LTC will increase substantially
in the next 30 years, as the table below illustrates:
240
Level of No. lives (000s) in:
241
More important may be the costs of future care, which have been projected
to increase from:
Product Design
242
claim or death.
Benefits are in the form of income for the duration of a valid claim
LTC as a rider to a whole life plan: In the event of satisfying the claims
criteria the death
benefit is accelerated and payable in monthly installments
LTC as an extension to IPI: Before NRA, IPI claims criteria and benefit
level are used. After this age, LTC claims criteria used are with the
same or increased level of benefits.Premiums may remain at the
same level, decrease, or stop at the change-over age.
243
monthly annuity to cover part or all of care costs for as long as care is
required.
Product Features
Claims Criteria
Claims can usually be triggered through physical disability or cognitive
impairment.
Typical claims criteria would be:
Failure of 3 ADLs is typically used as the point for payment of the full sum
assured, since this is the point when residential care will usually be
required.
Benefit Limits
245
• the length of the benefit period (eg 3 or 5 years)
• the total amount of benefits payable.
Benefit Escalation
Benefits may be level or indexed. Types of indexation:
Premiums
Premiums can be regular or single lump-sum.
Regular premium policies are generally reviewable (ie insurance company
can increase them at their discretion).
Guarantees are sometimes offered, for example, the premium rates may be
246
guaranteed to remain level for 10 years, but annually reviewable
thereafter.
Premium Waiver
Deferred Period
Typically this is 3 months, although there are also deferred periods of 6, 12,
24 and 36 months.
247
Other features
Since LTC is a protection product there is not
normally any surrender value or death benefit.
248
Consider the following LTC policy, with premiums payable continuously at
annual rate P̄ and:
• SA of $B pa
• 50% of SA payable on loss of 2 ADLs
• 100% of SA payable on loss of 3 or more ADLs.
We represent the life history underlying this contract using the following
model.
249
µ31- 1.Able
x+t
HH µ14
(<2 ADLs) HH x+t
6 µ21 µ 12 HH
x+t
2.Mild Dis-? x+t
j
H
24
ability (2
µ x+t- 4.Dead
ADLs)32
13 6 *
µx+t µx+t µ23
x+t
?
- 3.Disabled µ34
x+t
(≥3 ADLs)
Figure 10: A Markov model of long-term care insurance, allowing for mild disability.
250
d 1
V (t) = δ V 1 (t) + P̄ − µ12
x+t (V 2
(t) − V 1
(t))
dt
−µ13
x+t (V 3
(t) − V 1
(t)) + µ 14
x+t V 1
(t)
d 2 B
2
V (t) = δ V (t) − − µ21 x+t (V 1
(t) − V 2
(t))
dt 2
−µ23
x+t (V 3
(t) − V 2
(t)) + µ 24
x+t V 2
(t)
d 3
V (t) = δ V 3 (t) − B − µ31x+t (V 1
(t) − V 3
(t))
dt
−µ32
x+t (V 2
(t) − V 3
(t)) + µ 34
x+t V 3
(t)
d 4
V (t) = 0
dt
251
using the boundary conditions:
V i (ω − x) = 0 for i = 1, 2, 3, 4
where ω is the oldest age in the life table.
Inception/annuity approach
This method assumes that once a life is claiming, they cannot recover to a
non-claiming state.
We first introduce some notation:
(z ADLs)
• ix is the probability that a life aged x fails ≥ z ADLs.
(<z ADLs)
• t px is the probability that a life aged x survives to time t
without failing z or more ADLs.
(≥z ADLs)
• t px,d is the probability that a life aged x with current duration d
of having failed at least z ADLs survives to time t.
252
Consider the following LTC contract issued to a life aged x:
253
These can easily be calculated using tabulated values and a
spreadsheet.
If the policy is more complex, then we may be able to value it as separate
policies. For example, if:
254
Advantages of the multiple-state model approach
255
Note: In using a Markov model we are assuming that duration of disability
does not affect future transitions.
Example
(Faculty and Institute of Actuaries: Subject 105, September 2003: Question 14. Note that
this question is formulated in discrete time rather than continuous time just because it is a
pencil-and-paper exercise to be completed under exam conditions.)
A life insurance company uses the following multiple-state model for pricing and valuing
annual premium long-term care contracts, which are sold to lives that are healthy at outset.
256
0.Healthy - 1.Claim Level 1 - 2.Claim Level 2
HH
HH ?
j
H 3.Dead
Under each contract, the life company will pay the costs of long-term care while the
policyholder satisfies the conditions for payment. These conditions are assessed every
year on the policy anniversary, just before payment of the premium then due. If the
policyholder satisfies the conditions, the annual amount of the benefit payable is paid
immediately. A maximum of four benefit payments may be made under the policy, after
which time the policy expires. The policy also expires on earlier death.
Premiums are payable annually in advance under the policy until expiry, and are waived if a
benefit is being paid at a policy anniversary.
For lives at claim level 1, benefits of 60% of the maximum level are paid, while lives at
claim level 2 receive 100% of the maximum level. The current maximum level is GBP
50,000 per annum and is expected to increase by 6% per annum compound in the future.
257
pij
x is the probability that a life aged x in state i will be in state j at age x + 1 and the
insurer uses the following probabilities for all values of x:
p00
x = 0.87 p01
x = 0.1 p02
x = 0.0
p11
x = 0.6 p12
x = 0.3 p22
x = 0.6
(ii) A policyholder has already received two benefit payments at level 1, and is about to
receive a third benefit instalment. Calculate the reserves the office should hold for this
policy immediately after the benefit payment is made, if the policyholder is assessed as
entitled to either:
(a) benefit at level 1 = GBP 42,000 per annum
(b) benefit at level 2 = GBP 70,000 per annum
258
Reserve Transition
of 7% per annum
259
P
= = 5.578947P
1 − 0.87
1.06
Benefits
Assume benefits are just about to begin. Since benefits escalate at the same rate as the
discount rate, ignore interest.
0.6 × SA with prob = 0.6
2nd Payment =
SA with prob = 0.3
0.6 × SA with prob = 0.62
3rd Payment =
SA with prob = 0.36∗
260
(∗ Prob = 0.6 × 0.3 + 0.3 × 0.6)
0.6 × SA with prob = 0.63
4th Payment =
SA with prob = 0.324∗∗
t−1
P[claim starts at time t] = t−1 p00 01
x px+t−1 = (0.87) (0.1)
261
Hence:
∞
X
E [Benefits] = 114, 480 (0.87)t−1 (0.1)
t=1
0.1
= 114, 480 = 88, 061.54
1 − 0.87
Therefore, the equation of value is:
=⇒ P = 17, 064.43
(ii)(a) If the 3rd instalment is at level 1, then the 4th claim will be at level 1 with probability
0.6, or at level 2 with probability 0.3.
262
(b) If the 3rd instalment is at level 2, then the 4th can only be at level 2, and will occur with
probability 0.6.
1.07
Reserve = 70, 000 0.6 = 42, 800
1.05
263
8 Selection
• mortality
• morbidity
• any other characteristic of interest
Also, when a policyholder purchases a policy, they:
264
Scenario A: Company treats them as a single
homogeneous population. The premium the company should charge is 7.5
• equity (fairness)
• anti-selection
Examples of a population include
265
company Z in city M
We consider:
266
8.1 Temporary Initial Selection
An example of this can be seen in the mortality rates of ‘Permanent Assurance (whole life
and
endowment) policyholders 1991–94’ (C.M.I.R. 17 1999). The rates given in the table
pertain to male policyholders.
Notes:
267
• The mortality for lives who have more recently joined the insured population is lighter.
• As duration since policy inception increases some lives become less healthy
• The difference between the mortality of lives with different duration decreases as
duration increases
• In the U.K. a 2-year select period is used, while in North America 10 to 15 years is
common for the select period.
268
members.
In the table below consider the claim rates for IPI for deferred periods 1 week and 26
weeks for Males, individual policies 1987–94.
Deferred
269
8.2 Time selection
As an example we consider the mortality rates for Males, Permanent Assurances (CMIB
graduations) in the table below.
Note the values are for lives of the same age, sex and duration.
270
q[x] qx
AM92 AM92
Impact of Changes
Two of the ways in which effects of time selection can be minimised are:
272
investigations (eg 3–5 years).
θx
For example when estimating transition intensities µx = c it is usual to calculate
Ex
θx and Exc from data spanning 3–4 years. The idea is to minimise the scope for
time selection
Definition: Class selection is due to differences (in mortality) due to some permanent
feature
separating the populations.
273
(a) Males and females have different mortality and morbidity experiences.
Ex θx qx
Male 500 15 0.030
274
Mortality rates by sex: population B
Ex θx qx
Male 3,000 90 0.030
(b) Holders of term assurances and permanent assurances have different mortality
experiences.
275
Mortality rates by type of policy.
30 0.00048 0.00063
50 0.00197 0.00244
80 0.04383 0.07024
(c) People in different socio-economic classes may have different mortality and
morbidity rates.
276
Ways of dealing with class selection include
splitting the data by factors that may cause class selection.
Definition: This is the difference in mortality rates between two populations arising out of
the ability of lives in one subpopulation to take actions that are to the financial
disadvantage of an
insurer.
(a) Company A requires all applicants to undergo a medical test as part of policy
application while Company B does not.
278
Adverse selection occurs if the mortality experience of Company B is worse than that of A
because lives who know that they may fall ill (such that the premiums charged are
low given their risk)
purchase insurance from Company B.
(b) Smoking is associated with heavier mortality but UK standard tables are not split on
smoker/non-smoker basis.
Until 1981 all offices charged the same premium for smokers and non-smokers.
279
No problem if:
(ii) the offices not offering discounts were left insuring increasing proportion of
smokers
280
(c) A current issue in insurance underwriting is whether insurers should have access to
results of genetic tests done on applicants.
Arguments include:
• will mutation carriers use the knowledge of status to buy more insurance cheaply
• should insurers be able to ask for the
results from genetic tests previously taken
281
8.5 Selective Decrements
We consider examples:
(a) In life insurance policyholders, the most likely people to lapse their policies are those
in good health.
282
attractive to them
(c) Consider the mortality of active members (not retired) of a pension scheme. This
population:
• increases by new people employed (mainly healthy people)
• decreases by the people who retire early (mainly ill people retire early)
The selective nature of these ‘entrants’ and ‘leavers’ affects the mortality of the
active members.
As an example we consider a lives joining a population at age 30, consisting of two groups
A and B whose mortality at ages 30 and 31 are shown in the table.
283
Mortality rates for groups A and B
q[30] = 0.0025
q[30]+1 = 0.0025
q[30] = 0.0025
284
2 1
q[30]+1 = (0.003) + (0.002) = 0.0027
3 3
285
9 Some Demographic Topics
A single figure that summarises the mortality experience of a population enables easy
comparison.
Single Figure indices are formulas for calculating such a single figure:
• they are easy to assimilate, rather than a range of age-specific rates; but
• there is a loss of information in summarising and so care needs to be taken in the
construction and application of the indices
286
Crude Death Rate (CDR)
Total deaths
CDR =
Total exposure
P
dx
x
=
Ecx
P
x
Where:
(a)
Ecx dxc
P P
dx
x x Ex
CDR = =
Ecx
P
Total population
x
X Ecx
= µx
Total population
x
X
= wx µx
x
288
• the data requirements are minimal (just the total deaths and the total
population).
(c) Weaknesses of the CDR:
• CDR is heavily influenced by the age structure of the population.
Mortality Region A
≈ Mortality Region B
≈ Mortality of Country
CDR for Region A is influenced by the relatively high proportion of young people.
289
The country has, relatively, an even younger
population than either Region A or B.
X
SDR = wx µx (never SMR!)
x
s c
E
Where: wx = P sx c
Ex
x
are based on a standard population
We note that:
290
(a) For Region A, (with age specific Aµx ):
Ps
Ecx Aµx
x
SDRA =
Ecx
Ps
x
SDRA ≈ SDRB
291
• age specific mortality rates of the region
• age specific structure of the standard population (weights)
However, the weights (age specific structure of the standard population) may be unknown
or unreliably estimated.
We consider the case where the weights are only reliably known at specific times (eg
census times).
However the age specific structure of a standard population may only be known at census
dates.
This gives problems if we need to calculate the SDR at dates in between these
censuses.
292
Assumption:
SDR (at census) SDR (non-census)
=
CDR (at census) CDR (non-census)
Then we have that:
SDR (at census)
SDR (non-census) =
CDR (at census)
× CDR (non-census)
= F × CDR (non-census)
and the data requirements for CDR (non-census) are easily met even at non-census
times.
293
F is called the area comparability factor, and:
P s
Ecx µx
x
P s
Ecx
F = x
P
dx
x
P
Ecx
x
F is calculated at the census and assumed to remain constant until the next census
when it is updated.
294
The expected deaths are calculated using the age specific mortality rates for the
standard population.
Notes:
= 1.022(= 102.2%)
SMRB = 1.009(= 100.9%)
(c) The data requirements are:
295
• total number of deaths in the region
• population at each age group in the region
• age-specific mortality rates in standard population
This information is more likely to be known more reliably than the information for
the SDR (in particular the age specific population structure).
(d) The SMR is usually expressed as a percentage and:
• a region which has the same mortality as the standard population will have an
SMR of 100%
• if the SMR is greater than 100% then the region has heavier mortality than
the standard population.
• if the SMR is less than 100% then the region has lighter mortality than the
standard population.
296
Data for examples on single figure indices
297
Table 2: Age-specific mortality rates
298
• demand for food, power, services,
transport
• housing
• welfare services
• taxes
• labour costs
• national insurance contributions
We consider mathematical models and component models for population projections.
Mathematical Models
Mathematical models:
Definition:
Pt = Size of population at time t (t ≥ 0)
Then for the exponential we have:
Pt = P0 er t
For some growth parameter r .
300
Notes:
if r < 0, then Pt → 0
301
(population can become extinct after some time)
Neither of these is considered realistic.
We adjust the exponential model by introducing a factor that slows down the population
growth as the population increases.
d
Pt = r · Pt − k · Pt2
dt
Notes:
1 er t
Pt = =
c1 · e−r t + c2 c1 + c2 · er t
302
(b) The model has 3 parameters: r , c1 and c2 . Therefore is should give a better fit
than the exponential model with only 1 parameter.
(c) We have:
1
lim Pt = <∞
t→∞ c2
Also:
1
P0 = 6= 0
Pt c1 + c2
6
1
c2
1
c1 + c2
-
t
(d) The parameters can be estimated from data by least squares estimation or any
other method.
303
Problem with mathematical models
This method projects the population size and structure on the basis of:
(i) Start with an estimated population at time 0 subdivided by age, gender, etc.
304
(ii) Project mortality, fertility, migration rates for each age, gender etc. for each year into
the future.
305
(c) Future national immigration/emigration will depend on future economic conditions
and politics.
— End —
306