Hall and Gingerich 2004
Hall and Gingerich 2004
Peter A. Hall is Krupp Foundation Professor of European Studies and the Director
of the Minda de Gunzburg Center for European Studies at Harvard University.
Daniel W. Gingerich is a Graduate Associate of the Weatherhead Center for
International Affairs and a Ph. D. candidate in the Department of Government
at Harvard University.
Peter A. Hall
[email protected]
Daniel W. Gingerich
[email protected]
MPIfG Discussion Papers are refereed scholarly papers of the kind that are publishable in a peer-reviewed
disciplinary journal. Their objective is to contribute to the cumulative improvement of theoretical knowledge. The papers can be ordered from the institute for a small fee (hard copies) or downloaded free of
charge (PDF).
Downloads
http://www.mpifg.de
Go to Publications / Discussion Papers
Max-Planck-Institut fr Gesellschaftsforschung
Max Planck Institute for the Study of Societies
Paulstr. 3 | 50676 Cologne | Germany
Tel. +49 (0) 221 2767-0
Fax +49 (0) 221 2767-555
www.mpifg.de
[email protected]
Abstract
Using aggregate analysis, this paper examines the core contentions of the varieties of
capitalism perspective on comparative capitalism. We construct a coordination index
to assess whether the institutional features of liberal and coordinated market economies conform to the predictions of the theory. We test the contention that institutional complementarities occur across sub-spheres of the macroeconomy by examining the correspondence of institutions across sub-spheres and estimating the impact
of complementarities in labor relations and corporate governance on rates of growth.
To assess the stability of the institutional features central to the theory, we assess the
dynamics of institutional change in recent years. The evidence suggests that there are
powerful interaction effects among institutions across sub-spheres of the political
economy that must be considered if the economic impact of institutional change in
any one sphere is to be accurately assessed.
Zusammenfassung
Mit Hilfe von Aggregatdaten analysiert dieses Papier Kernaussagen des Varieties-ofCapitalism-Ansatzes. Um beurteilen zu knnen, ob die Aussagen der Theorie mit den
institutionellen Begebenheiten liberaler und koordinierter konomien bereinstimmen, konstruieren wir einen lndervergleichenden Index der konomischen Koordination. Wir berprfen die These von der institutionellen Komplementaritt zwischen den verschiedenen Sphren politischer konomien, indem wir das Zusammenwirken von Institutionen analysieren und den Einfluss komplementrer Institutionen
der Arbeitsbeziehungen und der Unternehmenskontrolle auf die Hhe von Wachstumsraten untersuchen. Wir diskutieren darber hinaus, wie stabil die institutionellen
Begebenheiten in den vergangenen Jahren waren. Im Ergebnis zeigen sich starke Interaktionseffekte zwischen den Sphren politischer konomien, die bercksichtigt
werden mssen, um die wirtschaftlichen Wirkungen institutionellen Wandels in einzelnen Sphren zu verstehen.
Contents
10
13
17
22
30
Conclusion
37
References
39
How do national variations in the institutions of the political economy affect economic performance? This question has been central to comparative political economy
for many years. However, most answers to it focus on institutions in a single sphere of
the political economy. In economics, there are large but separate literatures on labor
and financial markets. One explores the impact of labor regulations, social regimes,
and trade unions on growth or unemployment (Nickell 1997; OECD 1994; Calmfors/
Driffil 1988). The other considers the effects of accounting standards, the legal standing of owners or creditors, ownership patterns, and equity or bank-based finance on
levels of investment or growth (Carlin/Mayer 1999a, 1999b; LaPorta et al. 1998a;
Huang/Xu 1999; Mayer 1996). A similar separation is evident in political science.
Although neocorporatism can be defined in broad terms (cf. Katzenstein 1985;
Schmitter/Lehmbruch 1978), analyses of its economic impact usually focus on the
organization of the trade union movement, considering its interaction mainly with
the partisanship of governance (Cameron 1984; Alvarez et al. 1991; Garrett 1999).1 An
entirely different literature examines the structure of financial systems (Verdier 2000;
Cox 1986; Zysman 1984).2
However, there are good reasons to expect interaction effects among institutions
across spheres of the political economy. In recent years, significant interaction effects
have been found between monetary institutions and those governing wage coordination (Franzese 2002; Cukierman/Lippi 1999; Soskice/Iversen 2000; Iversen et al. 2000;
Iversen 1998; Hall/Franzese 1998). But investigation of such effects among other institutions has barely begun (cf. Amable 2000; Amable et al. 2001; Ernst 2002; Fehn/
Meier 2000; Caballero/Hamour 1998; Nicoletti et al. 2000).
The problem can be described as one of identifying institutional complementarities in
the macroeconomy. Economists have identified complementarities among the activities of firms: marketing strategies based on product customization, for instance, can
be complementary to computer-controlled machines on the production line (cf. Jai-
We are grateful to Alexander Kuo for research assistance and to the John D. and Catherine T.
MacArthur Foundation for a grant to Hall for research and writing. For helpful comments, we
thank James Alt, Bruno Amable, Moreno Bertoldi, Robert Boyer, Colin Crouch, Eckhard Ernst,
Peter Gourevitch, Torben Iversen, Bruce Kogut, Martin Hpner, Marino Regini, and Wolfgang
Streeck. An earlier version of this paper was presented to the American Political Science Association, August 2001. A shorter version has been published in German: Peter A. Hall and Daniel W.
Gingerich, Spielarten des Kapitalismus und institutionelle Komplementaritten in der Makrokonomie Eine empirische Analyse, in: Berliner Journal fr Soziologie 14, 2004, 532.
1
Hicks and Kenworthy (1998; cf. Kenworthy 1995) are a notable exception. They examine the
impact of neocorporatism construed as a broad system of cooperation; and a few other studies
do so as well, without, however, examining interaction effects among spheres of the economy
directly.
2
Less relevant to this paper but of equal importance is a literature on the economic impact of
variation in the institutions responsible for economic policy (cf. Drazen 2000; Persson /Tabelini 1994).
kumar 1986; Milgrom/Roberts 1990, 1995). It is plausible to posit analogous complementarities among the institutions structuring relations in the political economy
(Amable 2000). One set of institutions is complementary to another when its presence
raises the returns available from the other. Here, we refer to the returns to the actors
involved in the relevant activities that feed into national economic performance.3
The requirement for any investigation of this issue, however, is a theory specifying
why two or more institutions might be complementary to each other, and where such
complementarities are located in the political economy. Aoki (1994) offers important
observations about the issue but focuses only on the case of Japan. An important literature on comparative capitalism suggests that political economies contain such
complementarities (Crouch/Streeck 1997; Whitley 1999; Hollingsworth/Boyer 1997;
Albert 1993), but most contributions to it address a limited number of countries and
do not specify the complementarities in readily generalizable terms.4
In this context, a new body of work on varieties of capitalism is important (cf. Hall/
Soskice 2001b).5 Its formulations contain a theory about the nature of the institutional complementarities found in the political economies of the developed world.
Applying the new economics of organization to the macroeconomy, this literature
distinguishes among capitalist economies by reference to the means firms and other
actors use to coordinate their endeavors. It suggests that nations cluster into identifiable groups based on the extent to which firms rely on market or strategic modes of
coordination and that important complementarities can exist between the institutions
in different spheres of the political economy. From this follow many important contentions about variations in economic performance, comparative institutional advantage, national responses to globalization, and comparative public policy, which are
grounded in a rich set of comparative case studies (see the references in Hall/Soskice
2001b).6
However, the core postulates of the varieties of capitalism approach have not yet been
subjected to empirical tests based on aggregate analysis of a large number of cases. As
yet, we do not even have good measures for the character of coordination, the concept
3
4
5
Obviously, this leaves aside the question of how these returns are distributed, a matter that
may also be conditioned by the character of the institutions.
For important recent exceptions, see Amable (2000); Amable et al. (2001); Ernst (2002); Boyer
(1989).
This approach originates in early formulations by Soskice (1990a, 1990b) that build on the
literature about neocorporatism and regulation (cf. Katzenstein 1985; Boyer 1989) but add to
it a fuller appreciation for the role that employer networks play in the economy. It has subsequently been developed by Soskice and a number of other scholars, many of whom are contributors to Hall and Soskice (2001b).
Aggregate analysis has been applied to a few of the relatively specific propositions generated
by this approach (cf. Franzese 2001; Estevez et al. 2001; Iversen /Soskice 2000, 2001).
at the heart of the analysis. This poses many problems. Case studies have been used to
classify nations into general categories, but reliance on such broad classifications has
meant that a theory designed to offer insights about all the developed nations is sometimes misinterpreted to be one that speaks only to a few ideal types, and the position
of many nations within these categories remains ambiguous.
The object of this paper is to address these problems, by devising indicators for some
of the central concepts of the varieties of capitalism approach and subjecting some of
its core contentions to aggregate empirical tests. We begin by developing indices to
measure the character of coordination in key spheres of the political economy. We use
them and other measures to assess the plausibility of the account given by the varieties
of capitalism perspective about how behavior across the sub-spheres of the political
economy interlocks and how national political economies differ. We then examine the
core postulates of the theory about the presence of institutional complementarities in
the macroeconomy. Finally, we examine patterns of political adjustment and institutional change in order to assess the durability of the national distinctions identified by
this approach. Before considering specific propositions, we open with an overview of
the varieties of capitalism perspective.7
This approach originates in the early work of David Soskice (1990a, b), and the account given
of it here draws extensively on joint work with him (Hall/Soskice 2001a).
librium outcomes are dictated primarily by relative prices, market signals, and familiar marginalist considerations. In the other modality, firms coordinate with other
actors through processes of strategic interaction of the kind typically modeled by
game theory. Here, equilibrium outcomes depend on the institutional support available for the formation of credible commitments, including support for effective information-sharing, monitoring, sanctioning, and deliberation.8
Although instances of market and strategic coordination occur in all capitalist
economies, this approach contends that, in the spheres central to firm endeavor, the
balance between these two types of coordination varies across political economies. At
one end of the spectrum stand liberal market economies (LMEs) where relations between firms and other actors are coordinated primarily by competitive markets. At the
other end are coordinated market economies (CMEs) where firms typically engage in
more strategic interaction with trade unions, suppliers of finance, and other actors.9
Whether a firm coordinates its endeavors through market relations or strategic interaction is said to depend on the institutional setting. Where markets are imperfect and
there is substantial institutional support for the formation of credible commitments,
firms can be expected to rely more extensively on strategic coordination. Where markets are fluid and there is little support for such commitments, firms will rely more
heavily on market coordination. Accordingly there should be a correspondence between the institutional configuration of each sphere of the economy and the character
of coordination there.10
The distinction will be clearer if we describe a liberal and coordinated market economy. Market coordination is a familiar concept in neoclassical economics, and the
United States is a typical liberal market economy. Here, firms face large equity markets marked by high levels of transparency and dispersed shareholding, where firms
access to external finance depends heavily on publicly assessable criteria such as market valuation. Regulatory regimes allow hostile takeovers that depend on share price,
rendering managers sensitive to current profitability. Because trade unions are rela-
10
This list of the institutional correlates of effective strategic coordination is a familiar one that
draws on the conventional literature (cf. Ostrom 1990) but also includes the presence of a capacity for deliberation whose importance is outlined in Hall /Soskice (2001a).
The approach concentrates on cross-national variation because it examines spheres were national regulations and nationally specific institutions are especially important, but it acknowledges there can be additional variation across specific regions or sectors (cf. Campbell et al.
1991; Herrigel 1996).
Of course, the distinction between institutions and coordination is a narrow one, especially if
coordination is construed as rule-patterned behavior (cf. Calvert 1995). Here, institutions are
construed as rules and practices, more or less formal, that actors take into account when making decisions about what actions to undertake. These include the institutions generated by the
organizational setting (cf. Hall /Soskice 2001a: 9).
tively weak and employment protection low, labor markets are fluid and wage-setting
primarily a matter of contract between workers and individual employers. Because
labor markets are fluid, workers have incentives to invest in general skills that can be
taken to other jobs, and, because industry associations are weak, firms lack the capacity to mount the collaborative training programs that confer industry-specific skills.
Technology transfer is accomplished primarily by licensing or taking on expert personnel, and standards are usually set by market races. Top managers enjoy substantial
authority over all aspects of firm strategy, including layoffs. In such settings, many of
the relationships firms form with other actors are mediated by competitive markets.
Although there are variations among them, the United Kingdom, Ireland, Canada,
Australia and New Zealand are also generally identified by this approach as liberal
market economies.
Germany provides a good example of a coordinated market economy. Its firms are
closely connected by dense networks of cross-shareholding and membership in influential employers associations. These networks provide for substantial exchanges of
private information, allowing firms to develop reputations that permit them some
access to capital on terms that depend more heavily on reputation than share value.
Accordingly, managers are less sensitive to current profitability. In the presence of
strong trade unions, powerful works councils, and high levels of employment protection, labor markets are less fluid and job tenures longer. In most industries, wagesetting is coordinated by trade unions and employers associations that also supervise
collaborative training schemes, providing workers with industry-specific skills and
assurances of available positions if they invest in them. Industry associations play a
major role in standard-setting with legal endorsement, and substantial amounts of
technology transfer take place through interfirm collaboration. Hemmed in by powerful workforce representatives and business networks, top managers have less scope for
unilateral action, and firms typically adhere to more consensual styles of decisionmaking.
It should be apparent that, in order to perform their core functions, firms in coordinated market economies like that of Germany must engage in strategic interaction in
multiple spheres, although the institutions on which they rely and the quality of the
outcomes may vary from one to another. Austria, Japan, South Korea, Sweden, Norway, Finland, Denmark, Belgium, the Netherlands, and Switzerland are usually also
identified by those who adopt this approach as coordinated market economies.
10
We begin our analysis by examining the core contention of the varieties of capitalism
approach that the developed economies differ systematically from one another according to the extent to which firms depend on market or strategic coordination to
accomplish their endeavors. Of course, the character of coordination is difficult to
measure directly. However, as Hall and Soskice (2001a) point out, the nature of the
coordination present in any sphere of the economy depends on the type of institutions available to support it there. Accordingly, a factor analysis designed to identify
commonalities that may be unobservable in themselves but that correlate with a range
of observable variables provides an appropriate technique for identifying the character
of coordination (Harman 1976). By performing a factor analysis on a set of institutional measures that are commonly associated with one type of coordination or another, we can assess whether the dimensions of market and strategic coordination
posited by varieties of capitalism theory exist and where they are present. Varieties of
capitalism theory generates two hypotheses that can be tested using such an analysis:
H1: The character of coordination constitutes a key dimension stretching across spheres of
the political economy.
If this is correct, a factor analysis of variables representing the institutional conditions
associated with different types of coordination in various spheres of the political
economy should identify a single principal component loading on the relevant variables across spheres of the political economy.
H2: This dimension reflects variation along a spectrum running from market coordination to strategic coordination.
If this is correct, the underlying factor identified in the analysis should be positively
correlated with indicators for institutional support for strategic coordination and
negatively correlated with indicators for institutional support for market coordination.
The central obstacle to such an analysis is the paucity of relevant indicators available
for more than a few countries. The measurement of coordination poses special difficulties. In principle, types of coordination are observable, but intense observation is
required. Only one sphere has been the object of such observation, namely that of
wage bargaining. Accordingly, we employ two independent assessments of coordination in wage bargaining. The other variables used in the factor analysis are all indicators of institutional features of the political economy that can reasonably be said to
provide support for or to reflect the operation of one type of coordination or the
other. We have deliberately identified variables that extend across two important
spheres of the political economy, those pertinent to labor relations and corporate gov-
11
ernance. The observations were drawn from the 19901995 period, the latest for
which comparable data is available.
The variables employed in the factor analysis are as follows:11
Shareholder Power reflects the legal protection and likely influence over firms of ordinary
shareholders relative to managers or dominant shareholders. It is a composite measure of legal
regulations covering six issues: the availability of proxy voting, deposit requirements for
shares, the election of directors, the legal recourse available to minority shareholders, shareholders rights to issues of new stock, and the calling of shareholder meetings. Regulations
governing each issue are coded 0 or 1 and summed. Higher scores indicate that ordinary
shareholders enjoy more rights vis--vis managers and dominant shareholders (La Porta et al.
1998a: 1130).
Dispersion of Control indicates how many firms in the economy are widely held relative to
the number with controlling shareholders. Taking the smallest ten firms with market capitalization of common equity of at least $500 million at the end of 1995 as a sample of firms, it
reports the percentage that do not have a controlling shareholder, defined as one who controls, directly or indirectly, more than 10 percent of the voting rights in the firm. Higher values indicate that larger proportions of firms in the economy are widely held (LaPorta et al.
1998b: Table II, Panel B).
Size of Stock Market is the market valuation of equities on the stock exchanges of a nation as
a percentage of its gross domestic product in 1993 (Oecd.org / corporate affairs).
Level of Wage Coordination is the level at which unions normally coordinate wage-claims
and employers coordinate wage-offers where 3 represents the national level, 2 the intermediate
level, and 1 the firm level. Levels of coordination for unions and employers are assessed separately and averaged. Higher values indicate higher levels of coordination in wage-setting
(Layard / Nickell / Jackson 1991: 52).
Degree of Wage Coordination reflects estimates by the OECD Secretariat of the degree to
which wage bargaining is (strategically) coordinated by unions and employers along a scale on
which 3 indicates coordinated and 1 indicates uncoordinated. Observations are for 1994.
Higher values indicate higher levels of wage coordination (OECD 1997: 71).
Labor Turnover is an indicator of the fluidity of national labor markets and reports the number of employees who had held their jobs for less than one year as a percentage of all employ12
ees surveyed in 1995 (OECD 1997: 138).
The appropriateness of these variables for the analysis should be apparent from our
description of liberal and coordinated market economies. The first three variables
11
12
Further details of the derivation and definition of these measures can be found in the original
sources.
The value for New Zealand on this variable is estimated using a multiple imputation technique.
12
reflect institutional variation in the sphere of corporate governance of the sort highlighted by the varieties of capitalism approach. Where the balance of influence tilts
toward dominant shareholders, ownership is relatively concentrated, and equity markets are small, securing access to external finance and negotiating corporate control is
more likely to involve firms in strategic interaction within corporate networks. When
these conditions are reversed, issues of finance and corporate control are determined
more heavily by more competitive markets. The next three variables reflect relevant
variation in the sphere of labor relations. Two assess the level and degree of strategic
coordination in wage bargaining. Labor turnover reflects the degree to which workers
move from one firm to another via competitive labor markets.
Table 1
Uniqueness
Shareholder power
.705
.503
Dispersion of control
.821
.325
.638
.593
.721
.481
.512
.739
.874
.235
3.12
Note: Estimates calculated by principle factors method; factor presented above was the only one whose
eigenvalue exceeded 1.
Since the number of indicators available for such an analysis is limited if one wants to
include a large number of nations as we do, and the likelihood of some measurement
error is high, we entered the analysis with low expectations. Given these constraints,
the results are highly supportive of the terms the varieties of capitalism literature uses
to characterize political economies. We performed a factor analysis on these variables
using the principal factors method, and Table 1 reports the results. The analysis identifies an underlying factor along which the nations vary with an eigenvalue of 3.12,
and only one such factor with an eigenvalue above 1. All variables in the analysis are
highly correlated with this factor and their signs are congruent with the expectations
one would have for a factor representing the extent of market coordination relative to
strategic coordination in the political economy. These results suggest that the first two
hypotheses examined here should be accepted, and they tend to confirm the basic
contention of the varieties of capitalism literature that economies vary systematically
according to the relative balance of strategic and market coordination in their political
economies.
13
As we have noted, the varieties of capitalism approach classifies some nations as liberal market economies and others as coordinated market economies, although it also
anticipates variation within each category and nations that may lie beyond them (Hall/
Soskice 2001a). To assess whether this approach classifies countries correctly and
whether the basis for the classification is well-grounded, we test two further hypotheses.
H3: It is possible to identify a distinctive set of liberal market economies that make extensive use of market coordination and another set of coordinated market economies that
make extensive use of strategic coordination.
If this is correct, when the factor loadings are used to construct scores for each nation,
the nations identified by the theory as liberal market economies should be located
toward the market end of the dimension, and those identified as coordinated market
economies should be located closer to the strategic end.
To assess this hypothesis, we constructed an index based on the factor analysis described in the previous section and calculated scores on it for each of the OECD nations for which we have data. This can be construed as a coordination index assessing the overall balance of strategic coordination relative to market coordination in the
political economy.
Table 2 reports the factor scores on the relevant principal component for each nation,
standardized to vary between 0 and 1, with higher values indicating that strategic coordination is more important in the political economy relative to market coordination. The scores for all the nations that the varieties of capitalism literature classifies as
LMEs or CMEs fall into the portions of the spectrum that this literature would lead us
to expect. The US, UK, Canada, Ireland and Australia all have scores well below .50.
Austria, Germany, Norway, Japan, Belgium, Finland, Denmark, Sweden and Switzerland all have scores above .50, although Switzerlands score is lower than expected.
These results are broadly supportive of this third hypothesis.
Table 2 includes the two other indices in the literature most likely to tap this dimension, although Soskice (1990) focuses on wage coordination and both are based on
more subjective assessments of the cases (cf. Hicks/Kenworthy 1998). All three indices confirm the plausibility of the distinction between LMEs and CMEs, although
there are some differences in the ranking of countries inside each of these groups and
of some countries not assigned to them. For this reason, we would be cautious about
attributing too much significance to the precise score a nation receives on these scales
relative to the nations around it. It is clear that Austria is a highly-coordinated economy but whether Germany, Sweden or Norway is the next most-coordinated is less
certain. However, these findings tend to confirm the basic distinction the varieties of
capitalism literature draws between market-oriented and strategic coordination and
14
Table 2
Soskice index
Hicks-Kenworthy
corporatism score
.36
.17
Austria
.96
Belgium
.74
.67
Canada
.13
.04
Denmark
.70
.72
Finland
.72
.88
France
.69
1.5
.40
Germany
.95
3.5
.80
Ireland
.29
.07
Italy
.87
.44
Japan
.74
.77
Netherlands
.66
.58
New Zealand
.21
.14
Norway
.76
.96
Portugal
.72
Spain
.57
Sweden
.69
.97
Switzerland
.51
.55
United Kingdom
.07
.10
.02
Australia
United States
its contention that economies vary systematically according to the relative balance
between strategic and market coordination in the political economy.
As a further test, we have developed indicators for the character of coordination in
two of the most crucial spheres of the political economy, those of labor relations and
corporate governance, largely responsible for the allocation of labor and capital respectively. To construct the indicator for corporate governance, we performed a factor
analysis using the principal factors method on three variables that correspond to the
institutional features this approach emphasizes when distinguishing among systems of
corporate governance: shareholder power, dispersion of control, and size of the stock
market. An analogous indicator was developed for labor relations using a factor analysis on variables representing the level of wage coordination, the degree of wage coordination, and labor turnover. In both cases, the analysis identified only one factor
with an eigenvalue over 1 that we take to represent the relative balance between market and strategic coordination in that sphere of the political economy. From the factor
loadings, we created factor scores for all the OECD nations for which the relevant data
15
was available.13 On both indices, higher scores indicate higher levels of strategic coordination relative to market coordination.
We are now in a position to assess the following hypothesis derived from varieties of
capitalism theory:
H4: There is systematic variation among the developed economies such that those identified by the theory as LMEs display higher levels of market coordination in the spheres of
labor relations and corporate governance and those identified as CMEs display higher
levels of strategic coordination in both those spheres.
If this is correct, when arrayed in a two-dimensional space reflecting the character of
coordination, nations should not be distributed randomly across that space but at
least two clusters should be identifiable toward its two poles and the nations present
in those clusters should correspond to those the theory identifies as LMEs and CMEs.
Figure 1 provides the relevant evidence, arraying nations on a two-dimensional plot
with standardized scores for coordination in corporate governance on the X-axis and
standardized scores for coordination in labor relations on the Y-axis.
The results are broadly supportive of the hypothesis. As the regression line indicates,
there is a strong and statistically significant relationship in the predicted direction
between coordination in labor relations and corporate governance. Nations cluster
toward the southwest and northeast quadrants of the diagram, as the theory would
lead us to expect. Six nations, all normally identified by varieties of capitalism theory
as liberal market economies, cluster to the southwest, on or below the regression line.
The economies of northern Europe generally identified as CMEs cluster toward the
northeast in this two-dimensional space.
Japan and Switzerland are the two most obvious outliers. We are inclined to view their
position as the result of measurement error associated with the limitations of our
measure for coordination in corporate governance. The latter attaches considerable
weight to the size of the stock market and both nations have large stock markets relative to their GDP. But there is also extensive cross-shareholding in these nations not
picked up by our measure of shareholder dispersion because many of the relevant
holdings fall below our 10 percent cut-off (Windolf 2002; Roe 2000). Nevertheless,
13
For detailed description of the variables, see Section 2 above. The factor loadings were as follows. For coordination in corporate governance: shareholder power .629 (uniqueness .604),
dispersion of control .820 (uniqueness .327), size of stock market .718 (uniqueness .484). For
coordination in labor relations: level of wage coordination .728 (uniqueness .450), degree of
wage coordination .850 (uniqueness .277); labor turnover .551 (uniqueness .696). The standardized scores for each nation on these factors are reported in Table 2.
16
Figure 1
Labor relations
AUT
1
JAP
DEU
NOR
FIN
SWE
DEN
ITL
CHE
NTH
BEL
POR
FRA
.5
ESP
IRE
AUS
NZ
UK
Fitted values
CAN
US
.5
1
Corporate governance
these cross-shareholdings limit hostile takeovers and serve as vehicles for network
monitoring. In short, we think an accurate assignment of these cases would put them
into the northeast quadrant of the diagram. The coordination of labor relations in the
Netherlands and Belgium may also be underestimated here, reflecting OECD figures
that may underestimate coordination in labor relations. Given the potential for such
measurement error in indices taken entirely from external sources, however, the correspondence between the location of economies in Figure 1 and the account the varieties of capitalism literatures gives of such economies is striking.
The proximity of various nations to one another in this institutional space is also interesting and facilitates more fine-grained assessment of variations among the OECD
economies. Correcting for measurement error, there are four distinct clusters of nations. Among the liberal market economies, the United States and the United Kingdom appear as relatively pure cases, while four other liberal market economies stand
slightly apart by virtue of systems of corporate governance in which market coordination is not as fully developed. On the other side of Figure 1, the nations most often
identified as coordinated market economies all lie near or above the regression line,
indicating high levels of strategic coordination in both their labor and financial markets.
17
Four nations, Spain, Portugal, France and Italy all lie to the east in the figure but below the regression line. This is especially interesting because there has been some controversy about whether these nations are coordinated market economies or examples
of another distinctive type of capitalism often associated with high levels of state intervention on the supply side of the economy (Hall/Soskice 2001a; Rhodes 1997).
Figure 1 clarifies some of the issues that render these ambiguous cases. These nations
all have institutional capacities for strategic coordination in labor relations and corporate governance that are higher than those of LMEs. However, their capacities for strategic coordination in labor relations tend to be lower than those in northern Europe,
perhaps because their union movements are still divided along what used to be called
confessional lines. Although strategic coordination is clearly more important in these
nations than in liberal market economies, there may be systematic differences in the
operation of southern, as compared to northern, European economies.14
Although we have focused on corporate governance and labor relations as the two
most important spheres of the economy, the varieties of capitalism approach also expects systematic variation, between LMEs and CMEs, across other spheres of the political economy, including those associated with product-market competition, social
protection, vocational training, and interfirm relations more generally. Much of the
force of the varieties of capitalism approach as a theory of comparative capitalism
rests on its claim to be able to specify systematic variations across nations that extend
to many spheres of the political economy. We turn now to assessment of that claim.
Varieties of capitalism analysts argue that, where labor relations are based on high levels of job mobility and firm-level wage-setting, training systems that provide general
skills through formal education will be more efficient than collaborative training
schemes that confer industry-specific skills, because workers who must frequently
shift jobs have strong incentives to acquire the general skills that qualify them for
other positions. Conversely, where labor relations are based on strong unions and
coordinated wage-bargaining, it will be more efficient for firms to operate collaborative training schemes conferring high levels of industry-specific skills. High wages set
at the industry level encourage workers to acquire industry-specific skills, and they
make it more difficult for non-training firms to poach workers by offering wage pre-
14
The varieties of capitalism literature acknowledges that such differences may exist. Those
between the industry-coordinated economies of northern Europe and group-coordinated
economies of Asia have been elaborated most fully (cf. Soskice 1999).
18
miums. The organizations that coordinate wages can also be used to coordinate training systems (Finegold/Soskice 1988; Culpepper 2001).
For similar reasons, this approach expects a relationship between the character of corporate governance and the character of interfirm relations. Where the institutions of
corporate governance limit the demands on firms to maximize current profitability or
shareholder value, firms are said to find it easier to enter into collaborative arrangements with other firms, for the purposes of research, product development or technology transfer. Facing fewer pressures from financial markets, firms can make more
credible commitments to the incomplete contracts and co-specific investments that
such collaboration requires. Conversely, where fluid capital markets facilitate the
movement of funds from one endeavor to another, it will be more efficient for firms to
access technology by acquiring other enterprises or new personnel and to invest in
assets that can be switched to other uses as market opportunities emerge, rather than to
engage in long-term collaboration with other firms (Casper 1999; Hall/Soskice 2001a).
Estevez et al. (2001) argue that social policies providing generous employment and
unemployment protection will be complementary to production strategies based on the
use of specific skills because they provide incentives to workers for acquiring those
skills (cf. Mares 2000). Hall and Soskice (2001a; Soskice 1999) argue that high levels of
product-market regulation may be complementary to systems of corporate governance
that encourage network monitoring, to wage coordination, and to interfirm collaboration in research and development because they limit the intensity of competition in
product markets that might otherwise undermine cooperation in these other spheres.
Therefore, they expect to see some correspondence, if sometimes a loose one, between
institutional practices across these spheres.
The varieties of capitalism perspective also identifies potential complementarities between institutional arrangements in the political economy and the strategy of firms.
Where strong trade unions or regulatory regimes inhibit layoffs and facilitate the formation of credible commitments among firms or between a firm and its employees,
the theory suggests that firms will often find it efficient to develop corporate strategies
that turn on close cooperation with their employees and other firms. Conversely,
where fluid labor markets facilitate layoffs and dispersed financial markets frequently
demand them, firms are said to find such cooperative arrangements less advantageous. With such reasoning, the approach contends that firm strategy will vary systematically across nations with the kind of institutional support their political economies provide for different types of coordination (cf. Hall/Soskice 2001a; Lehrer 2001).
19
In short, the varieties of capitalism literature contends that systematic variation across
nations is present not only in the spheres of labor relations and corporate governance
but across many other spheres of the political economy.15 To assess this contention,
we have sought indicators for the types of variation in institutional practices the theory emphasizes. We have found indicators for relevant types of institutional variation
across seven spheres. For labor relations and corporate governance, we use the same
indicators employed in the preceding analysis. The others are as follows:
Social Protection refers to the level of support provided to the unemployed and to limitations
on the right of firms to lay off workers. We measure it by combining the indices of unemployment protection and employment protection devised by Estevez et al. (2001) using
weights for each generated by the principal component that appears when a factor analysis is
applied to the two indices. Higher values indicate higher levels of social protection.
Product Market Regulation refers to the limits placed on competition in product markets by
the regulatory restrictions that national governments impose on businesses. The measure is
based on an OECD survey of many types of regulatory practices combined into a composite
measure through multi-level factor analysis by Nicoletti et al. (2000: 80). Higher values indicate product market regulations more restrictive of competition.
Training Systems are assessed with a view to establishing the extent of institutional support a
nation provides for the development of vocational skills in young workers beyond what they
secure in formal secondary or university education. In general, this entails apprenticeship
schemes or training programs dependent on the collaborative involvement of firms. The
measure is based on the principal component that emerges from a factor analysis on two variables: the number of pupils in vocational training as a proportion of those in general education and the mean scores on a literacy test secured by a sample of workers between the ages of
20 and 25 who left school before completing secondary education (United Nations 1999: xxx;
OECD 1997b: 141). Higher values indicate higher levels of institutional support for this kind
of vocational training.
Interfirm Relations refer to the institutionalized practices that link firms to other firms producing goods and services. Of particular relevance is the extent to which firms collaborate with
others to secure access to new technology or markets relative to their reliance on competitive
market relations for such purposes. Mergers and acquisitions are typical of the latter. Accordingly, the measure is based on the annual number of mergers and acquisitions in a nation
during 19901997 expressed as a ratio of its population (Pagano/Volpin 2000: Table 4). We
reverse the direction of the measure so that higher values indicate more inter-firm collaboration.
15
Note that we make no claims here about why this systematic variation occurs nor do we assess
claims about its origins. It may be encouraged by the presence of complementarities among
these spheres but it may also arise because institutions diffuse together or as the result of complex political processes. Our concern here is simply to assess whether the variation the varieties of capitalism approach posits across political economies is present there.
20
To assess the ancillary claim that systematic variation in the institutions of the political economy will be associated with distinctive types of firm structures and strategies,
we have also sought measures for the latter, as follows:
Managerial Prerogative refers to the extent to which firms concentrate control over their
operations in the hands of top management. On the premise that compensation will correspond to the level of responsibility they are assigned for the firms operations, our measure is
the average compensation of chief executive officers as a ratio of the compensation of average
production workers in manufacturing in 1999 (Economic Policy Institute 2001: xx). Higher
values indicate higher levels of managerial prerogative.
Employment Tenure is a measure of the length of time employees typically stay with the same
firm, assessed here by median employer tenure in 1995 (OECD 1997: 138). This can be read as
a reflection of the extent to which firm strategies turn on the development of close relations
with a stable workforce rather than on production regimes that can be operated by more transient and potentially less-skilled labor.
Firm Strategy is a composite measure tapping many of the core practices of firms, including
the use they make of multidivisional project teams, participatory work teams, alliances with
other firms, close, voice-based relations with suppliers, long-term relations with investors, and
cooperative labor-management relations built on employment guarantees. Each practice has
been coded on a 3 point scale and combined via factor analysis by Hicks and Kenworthy
16
(1998: 1649). Higher values indicate firm strategies that make more extensive use of these
cooperative practices.
16
This measures uses the average 196089 scores for a factor that Hicks and Kenworthy label
firm-level cooperation which includes some further variables assigned low weights that we
do not enumerate here.
21
17
18
The coefficient between corporate governance and firm strategy just misses significance at the
.05 level.
Although some analysts associate institutional congruence of these sorts with institutional
complementarities, on the grounds that the search for greater efficiencies will motivate firms
to seek and support congruent practices, precisely why such congruence exists remains an
open question. It may well be conditioned by processes of institutional emulation in which
analogous institutions in multiple spheres diffuse together or by broader political processes
that we do not address here.
22
Table 3
Firm strategy
.615
(.007)
Employment tenure
.694
(.001)
Managerial prerogative
.794
(.006)
different types of coordination in the political economy, as varieties of capitalism theory predicts. Table 3 provides further evidence for this contention by comparing the
relationship between three indicators for corporate strategy and national scores on the
coordination index. In each case, there is a strong and statistically significant correlation in the direction posited by the theory.
Up to this point, our results indicate that the patterns in institutionalized practices
that the varieties of capitalism perspective expects to see across the developed economies are present there. We turn now to one of the most important contentions in that
perspective, namely the claim that there is not only some congruence among institutional practices in different spheres of the economy but that, in some cases, these
practices can be complementary to one another. Following this literature, we define
complementarity as follows: one set of institutional practices can be said to be complementary to another when each raises the returns available from the other. Although these institutions may also have distributive effects that increase the returns to
some actors relative to others, we are concerned here with returns to the economy as a
whole of the sort normally reflected in aggregate economic performance.
Our analysis focuses on the potential for complementarities between the sphere of
corporate governance and the sphere of labor relations. Following Aoki (1994), Hall
and Soskice (2001a) develop a theoretical rationale for why such complementarities
should exist and in what sorts of institutional practices they consist, based on the importance of coordination to the success of a firms endeavors. They argue that institutional practices in the sphere of corporate governance that encourage crossshareholding and concentrate control in the hands of management, thereby limiting
the potential for hostile takeovers and providing firms with access to finance that
turns more heavily on reputational monitoring than current profitability, enhance the
efficiency of institutional practices in the sphere of labor relations that provide high
23
levels of employment security and long job tenures as well as forms of wage-setting
that revolve around strategic interaction between employers associations and trade
unions.19 The logic is that firms that do not have to sustain current profitability in the
face of a fluctuating economy are better placed to make credible commitments to
their employees about wages and job security and therefore better able to realize the
gains available from utilizing production regimes based on such commitments. This
combination of institutions corresponds to the institutional patterns the varieties of
capitalism perspective sees in CMEs.
Conversely, where firms are more dependent on dispersed equity markets, face the
prospect of hostile takeovers, and confront regulations that give shareholders more
power relative to stakeholders, the autonomy of the firm and its managers will be
more dependent on current profitability. Here, labor markets allowing for high levels
of labor turnover and competitive wage-setting will be more efficient, because they
enable managers to reduce wages or staffing levels more quickly in response to fluctuations in current profitability, and allow the kind of labor relations that permit
firms to exploit the high levels of capital mobility available in such economies. This
combination of institutional practices corresponds to the case of a classic LME.
If the institutionalized practices characteristic of relatively pure liberal or coordinated
market economies in these two spheres are complementary to each other, we should
expect to see an impact on aggregate economic performance. Our indicator for performance will be rates of economic growth per capita measured in purchasing-parity
terms, widely accepted as a good measure of overall economic performance and appropriate for testing postulates about the general efficiency of the economy. However,
this measure provides an exceptionally hard test for institutional analyses such as
these. Because aggregate rates of growth depend on the efficiency of the entire economy, specific institutions will have to make substantial contributions to it to increase
aggregate rates of growth.
We begin by exploring interaction effects between institutions in the spheres of corporate governance and labor relations. As summary measures for the character of institutions in these two spheres, we used the indices for labor relations and corporate
governance developed in section 3. High values of these indices reflect institutions
more closely approximating those associated with CMEs, of the sort that allow for
more effective strategic coordination, and lower values reflect institutions associated
with LMEs where market coordination is more feasible. We estimate the interaction
effects between these two variables and their impact, with a range of appropriate controls standard in the growth literature, on annual rates of per capita economic growth
for OECD nations from 1971 to 1997, taking three different econometric approaches
19
When we say that one institutional practice enhances the efficiency of another, this means that
its presence increases the returns available from using the other institutional practice.
24
to the panel data.20 Initially, we employed a model based on ordinary least squares
regression with panel-corrected standard errors (PCSE; Beck/Katz 1995) of the following form:
Yit = 0 + 1CiLR + 2CiCG + 3CiLR CiCG + 4 lnGDPi + 5Intit + 6it + 7ToTit + 8Dit + it
(1)
where CLRi represents the character of coordination in labor relations in country i and
CCGi represents the character of coordination in its sphere of corporate governance.
This model is used to test the following hypothesis derived from the varieties of capitalism perspective on institutional complementarities:
H6: When there are higher levels of market (strategic) coordination in the sphere of labor
relations or corporate governance, rates of economic growth increase as the level of market
(strategic) coordination in the other sphere increases.
If this is correct, the interaction term in the model, CLRi* CCGi, should be statistically
significant and positive. A significant coefficient indicates that the impact of coordination in one sphere is dependent on the character of coordination in the other sphere,
and a positive coefficient indicates that analogous types of coordination in the two
spheres raise rates of growth.
The controls employed here are standard for estimating rates of economic growth:
lnGDPi is the log of gross domestic product per capita for country i at the beginning
of the period controlling for catch up effects that generate higher rates of growth in
nations at lower levels of economic development. Intit represents international demand conditions measured by the average rate of growth for our sample countries in
period t weighted by the trade openness of country i. it is the countrys rate of inflation measured by the rate of increase in its consumer price index. In the developed
world, where rates of inflation are moderate, we expect them to be positively related
to rates of growth. ToTit is the percentage change in the terms of trade of country i
weighted by trade openness: adverse movements should lower rates of economic
growth. Dit is the dependency ratio measured as the share of the population below the
age of 15 or above the age of 65. A higher proportion of dependents is expected to
lower rates of economic growth.
20
The nations included were those for which data was available to construct the indices for
coordination in labor relations and corporate governance. See the Table 3 for the full list. Because we think there is substantial measurement error in the placement of Japan and Switzerland on the CG index, they were excluded from these estimations. When they are included,
the sign on the interaction variable remains positive but it is statistically significant only in the
estimation using OLS with panel-corrected standard errors.
25
(2)
where Xit is a Kx1 vector of time- and panel-varying independent variables, Zi is a Jx1
vector of panel-varying but time-invariant independent variables, and vit is an error
term where ui are scalar constants representing panel-specific fixed effects and the
error term is vit = ui + wit such that: E(ui) = E(wit) = 0, E(ui wit) = 0; E(ui uj) = u2, if i
= j and otherwise 0; E(wit wjs) = w2, if i = j and t = s and otherwise 0; and E(ui Xit') =
E(ui Zi') = E(wit Xit') = E(wit Zi') = 0.
If the panel-specific effects and independent variables are still correlated even after the
latter have been transformed, the random-effects model will be biased, and Hausman
(1978) has produced a test for such correlation, based on the difference between the
coefficients and covariance matrices of the fixed-effects and random-effects estimators. Since this test indicates potential bias in our random-effects model, we also develop a third set of estimates, employing an instrumental variables technique suggested by Hausman and Taylor (1981). It produces a standard fixed-effects estimator
for all variables that vary over time and space. To produce coefficient estimates on the
time-invariant variables, the technique utilizes the time-variant variables assumed to
21
The test measures the difference between the ratio of the squared sum of residuals over time,
summed over all panels, to the sum of the squared errors from equation 1.
26
Table 4
PCSE
International demand
conditions (it)
.416***
(.038)
.793***
(.057)
.574***
(.056)
Inflation (it)
.212***
(.023)
.130***
(.028)
.133***
(.034)
1.02
(2.66)
.347
(2.69)
1.76
(2.41)
.573***
(.122)
.468***
(.132)
.403**
(.168)
ln GDP0 (i)
.453
(.424)
.477***
(.167)
2.47***
(.914)
Coordination in labor
relations (i)
4.20***
(1.58)
4.89***
(1.83)
7.80***
(2.72)
Coordination in corporate
governance (i)
1.67***
(.640)
1.10
(.743)
2.55**
(1.22)
Labor relations*
corporate governance (i)
5.81***
(1.64)
6.06***
(1.91)
8.75***
(2.76)
LM
9.17
Hausman test
79.7
n.a.
n.a.
486
486
486
Note: *** indicates the coefficient is significant at the 99% level, ** at the 95% level, and * at the 90%
level. Standard errors are in parentheses.
This fixed-effects estimator is consistent, if less efficient than the alternative 2SLS random
effects estimator suggested by Hausman and Taylor would be, but a random-effects estimator
constructed in this way failed the Hausman specification test.
27
Table 5
Labor
relations
.25
.5
.75
8.2
(5.5, 10.8)
7.9
(5.2, 10.5)
7.7
(4.8, 10.4)
7.4
(4.5,10.3)
7.1
(4.1, 10.2)
.25
7.0
(4.2, 9.8)
7.1
(4.3, 9.9)
7.2
(4.5, 10.0)
7.3
(4.7, 10.1)
7.4
(4.5, 10.4)
.5
5.7
(2.5, 8.9)
6.2
(3.3, 9.2)
6.7
(3.9, 9.5)
7.2
(4.4, 10.0)
7.7
(4.8, 10.5)
.75
4.9
(.76, 8.3)
5.4
(2.1, 8.7)
6.3
(3.3, 9.2)
7.1
(4.3, 9.9)
8.0
(5.2, 10.8)
3.3
(1.2, 7.8)
4.5
(.80, 8.3)
5.8
(2.6, 9.0)
7.0
(4.1, 9.8)
8.2
(5.4, 11.1)
28
In order to test this hypothesis, we use the coordination index developed in Section 2
to measure levels of market and strategic coordination across these two spheres of the
political economy. We estimate the effect of coordination on annual rates of per capita economic growth for OECD nations from 1971 to 1997 using a model of the following form:
Yit = 0 + 1Ci + 2Ci 2 + 3 lnGDPi + 4Intit + 5it + 6ToTit + 7Dit + it
(3)
where Ci is the value of the coordination index measuring the balance of market and
strategic coordination in the political economy for country i. If the relationship between
growth and coordination is U-shaped, b1 should be negative and b2 positive. The controls are the standard ones used previously and, once again, we estimated the model
using three specifications to cope with the potential for bias arising from collinearity
between the time-invariant measure of coordination and panel-specific effects.
Table 6
PCSE
International demand
conditions (it)
.467***
(.037)
.822***
(.055)
.576***
(.049)
Inflation (it)
.177***
(.024)
.132***
(.026)
.115***
(.035)
3.22
(2.40)
.776
(2.42)
.676
(2.51)
.413***
(.113)
.368***
(.121)
.335**
(.157)
ln GDP0 (i)
1.82***
(.540)
.490**
(.210)
2.20***
(.792)
5.72***
(1.52)
3.63***
(1.47)
6.74***
(2.21)
5.40***
(1.45)
4.19***
(1.45)
6.17***
(2.09)
LM
36.4
Hausman test
103.0
n.a.
n.a.
540
540
540
Table 6 reports the results of these three estimations. In all, the coefficients on coordination are significant, of the same sign, and of similar magnitude, increasing our confidence in the results. The significance and signs of the coefficients on C and C2 indicate that the relationship between coordination and economic growth is nonlinear.
Using the fixed-effects model for the simulation, Figure 3 shows the estimated relationship between coordination and growth when the control variables are at their
means. The U-shaped relationship is apparent. Where the institutional structure of
29
Figure 3
7.5
7
0
.5
Coordination index
Market coordination
1
Strategic coordination
the political economy allows for higher levels of market coordination or higher levels
of strategic coordination, estimated growth rates are higher than they are when there
is more variation in the types of coordination present in the political economy.
These results suggest that the varieties of capitalism approach to institutional complementarities, built on the distinction between market and strategic coordination,
has real merit. When complementary institutions are present across spheres of the
political economy, rates of economic growth are higher. The institutional complementarities identified by this perspective appear to offer general efficiencies.
30
On this point, our thinking has been influenced by conversations with Robert Fannion and
Gavyn Davies.
31
Table 7
H-T IV FE
PCSE
19851997
RE
H-T IV FE
PCSE
International demand
conditions (it)
.325***
(.044)
.685***
(.067)
.374***
(.058)
.504***
(.078)
.971***
(.120)
.660***
(.091)
(it)
.012
(.035)
.085**
(.042)
.018
(.042)
.049
(.054)
.004
(.063)
.032
(.066)
2.21
(2.9)
.951
(2.94)
1.08
(2.88)
9.10**
(4.55)
9.38**
(4.65)
5.31
(3.83)
.496***
(.172)
.456**
(.200)
.226
(.204)
.644***
(.188)
.553**
(.238)
.422**
(.211)
ln GDP0 (i)
.756
(.644)
.988***
(.219)
1.30
(1.07)
2.18***
(.654)
.388**
(.167)
3.32***
(.887)
Coordination in labor
relations (i)
8.75***
(2.39)
8.92***
(2.55)
7.38**
(2.96)
4.15*
(2.21)
4.08*
(2.26)
5.53*
(3.31)
Coordination in corporate
governance (i)
.993
(.907)
.348
(.982)
1.39
(1.29)
1.26
(.962)
.468
(.968)
2.11
(1.42)
Labor relations*
corporate governance (i)
9.64***
(2.49)
1.23
8.22***
(3.05)
_
4.48*
(2.35)
LM
9.57***
(2.67)
_
.025
4.16*
(2.41)
_
6.04*
(3.11)
_
Hausman test
53.0
n.a.
n.a.
30.4
n.a.
n.a.
252
234
impact in an earlier period. For this purpose, we estimated the models for the economic impact of complementarities between coordination in labor relations and corporate governance over two time periods, 19711984 and 19851997 (see equation 1).
Once again, three estimation techniques were employed to accommodate the potential for panel specific effects, although a LM indicates that estimates based on panelcorrected standard errors are relatively unbiased by such effects. These estimations are
used to test the following hypothesis:
H8: Secular economic developments over the past two decades have not altered the efficiency of the institutional complementarities posited by the varieties of capitalism perspective between labor relations and corporate governance.
If this is correct, the coefficient on the interaction term between coordination in labor
relations and corporate governance, CLRi* CCGi, should be positive and statistically
significant across both periods.
The results of the estimation are presented in Table 7. For the 19711984 period, the
coefficients on the interaction term are positive, statistically significant, and larger
than those for the entire 19711997 period (see Table 4). In the 19851997 period, the
coefficients on the interaction term diminish in size but they remain positive and just
miss statistical significance at the .05 level, as does the coefficient on coordination in
32
labor relations. These findings do not strongly confirm the hypothesis but neither do
they show it should be rejected. Institutional complementarities of the sort posited by
the varieties of capitalism perspective seem to have had a larger impact on levels of
economic growth in earlier decades and a smaller impact in recent years but one that
remains nonnegligible.
Two broad lines of explanation could account for this trend. Secular developments
may have reduced the returns available from these complementarities. Alternatively,
the complementarities may still be operative but their impact on cross-national differences in growth overwhelmed by recent developments for which we do not control in
these equations. The latter could include cross-national differences in economic policy, confidence effects arising from asset booms, or technology races that privilege first
movers. We cannot currently discriminate between these explanations. However,
these results lend some credence to the view that secular economic changes may be
diminishing the effectiveness of existing institutions, which should increase pressures
for institutional change.
Political Dynamics
In this context, the political dynamics of institutional change become especially important, and the varieties of capitalism literature advances a particular view of such
dynamics, built on the view that the market-oriented settings of liberal market
economies encourage firms, holders of capital, and workers to invest in switchable
assets, whereas institutional support for strategic interaction in coordinated market
economies encourages higher levels of investment in specific assets (Hall/Soskice
2001a; Iversen/Soskice 2000). In LMEs, fluid markets that facilitate the transfer of
resources among uses enhance the returns to switchable assets. In CMEs, better institutional support for the formation of credible commitments reduces the risks of investing in co-specific assets whose value depends on the cooperation of others and
that cannot readily be switched to other uses if that cooperation is not forthcoming.
This divergence in patterns of investment is significant because each generates a different politics. In the face of an exogenous shock threatening returns to existing activities, holders of mobile assets will be tempted to exit those activities to seek higher
returns elsewhere, while holders of specific assets have higher incentives to exercise
voice in defense of existing activities (Hirschman 1964). The argument is analogous
to the distinction often drawn between a Hecksher-Ohlin world, where factors are
mobile and shifts in relative prices (of the sort associated with increasing economic
openness) generate conflict between the holders of basic factors, such as capital and
labor, and a Ricardo-Viner world, where factors of production are sector-specific and
shifts in relative prices inspire intersectoral conflict that unites employers and workers
in defense of sectoral interests (cf. Hiscox 2001; Frieden /Rogowski 1996; Alt et al.
1996; Rogowski 1989).
33
From this perspective, the varieties of capitalism literature argues that the initial political response to contemporary economic challenges will vary across liberal and coordinated market economies. In LMEs, the response will be highly market-oriented.
When returns to existing activities are threatened, holders of mobile assets, such as
workers with general skills or owners of capital on fluid equity markets, will tend to
shift to new activities. In general, they will be interested in rendering markets even
more fluid. Where nations respond to shocks by relying on markets to adjust prices
and wages, however, substantial shifts in the distribution of income may occur of the
sort reflected in increasing income inequality. Such distributive effects are likely to
increase conflict between those with and without market-power, namely conflict of a
class character, notably in arenas responsible for the regulation of income, such as
the sphere of industrial relations.
In coordinated market economies, by contrast, the varieties of capitalism perspective
expects similar economic challenges to inspire a different political response, mediated
by higher levels of asset specificity. When returns to existing activities are threatened,
holders of specific assets, such as workers with industry-specific skills and owners of
enterprises deeply invested in co-specific assets, will find it difficult to shift to new
activities. As a result, they will be less inclined to favor deregulatory initiatives that
increase market competition and more inclined to demand institutional support for
existing activities. The result is likely to be a politics of regulatory defense that may
well also be conflictual but will unite workers and employers more often in crossclass coalitions of sectoral defense (cf. Swenson 1995; Wood 2001; Thelen/Kume
2000).
These postulates about political dynamics are important because they suggest that the
response to contemporary economic shocks is likely to produce quite different institutional outcomes in liberal and coordinated market economies. Although all capitalist
economies use markets to adjust and will render some more flexible in the face of
economic shocks, this analysis anticipates more and more-rapid deregulation in liberal market economies, where there should be more political support for it, than in
coordinated market economies, where cross-class coalitions arise to support existing
regulatory regimes. The perspective anticipates some conflict and change in all nations, including some liberalization in CMEs, but it also expects divergent institutional adjustment paths across different types of political economies.
In order to assess whether this perspective accurately models the response to recent
economic challenges, we examine a number of indicators. As the approach predicts,
levels of income inequality are not only higher in liberal than coordinated market
economies; they have also increased much more rapidly there in recent years (see Fig-
34
ure 4).24 This is what would be expected if LMEs respond to economic challenges by
relying more heavily on competitive markets to reset wages and prices.
We find similarly divergent outcomes in the sphere of industrial relations. Between
the 1970s and 1990s, trade unions were dramatically weakened in liberal market
economies. The proportions of the labor force belonging to a union or covered by
collective bargaining agreements fell by a third. By contrast, trade unions remained
relatively robust in coordinated economies, where 76 percent of the workforce was
covered by a collective bargaining agreement on average in the late 1990s, compared
with 38 percent in liberal economies (see Table 8). In the crucial sphere of labor relations, the response to recent economic challenges has reinforced, rather than undermined, institutional differences between liberal and coordinated market economies.
To what extent have such differences declined in other spheres over this period? To
form an assessment, we assemble indicators for the character of institutional practices
in six spheres relevant to the varieties of capitalism arguments. The observations are
24
For the empirical analysis in this section of the paper, we adopt the classification of political
economies that Hall and Soskice (2001a) use, terming those that they do not classify defintively as liberal or coordinated market economies, mixed market economies. Portugal, Spain,
France and Italy are in the latter category.
35
Table 8
LMEs
MMEs
1980s
1990s
1980s
1990s
1980s
1990s
55
53
46
31
33
33
28
15
Bargaining coverage
76
76
58
38
34
79
89
13
Bargaining level
1.7
1.8
2.3
2.5
1.8
11
Industrial relations
Social protection
Employment protection
2.3
2.3
1.0
1.0
3.5
14
Benefit entitlements
29
36
24
24
23
15
31
107
23
28
22
15
19
27
17
24
41
18
22
22
16
20.2
26
11
38
1713
1633
1810
1831
1812
1728
.24
.25
.28
.33
16
.31
.31
9.7
10.1
7.3
7.4
11.0
10.6
CEO compensation
343
506
48
414
801
93
332
570
72
Corporate governance
Stock mkt. capitalization
36
61
69
51
96
88
14
31
121
2.4
2.0
17
.66
.91
38
2.7
2.1
22
22
26
18
22
23
24.2
27.9
15
100
115
15
100
118
18
100
166
66
68
69
64
67
55
56
Sources: Ebbinghaus / Visser (2000); Traxler et al. (2000); OECD (1994: 65, 179; 1995: 42, 52; 1997a: 5, 7, 138;
1998: 18; 1999: 57, 241); MacFarlan / Oxley (1996: A1); Schludi et al. (1998: 2.3.1); LeMaitre et al. (1997: 141,
A1); Luxembourg Income Data Studies (2001); Economic Policy Institute 2000; Financial Times 8 Sept (2000:
11).
drawn from the mid-1980s and the latest point in the 1990s for which data were available. They are reported in Table 8. We distinguish among liberal market economies,
coordinated market economies, and a third group of nations possessing many of the
institutional features associated with strategic coordination but termed here mixed
market economies because they are not definitively classified into the other two categories by the varieties of capitalism literature.25
25
As labeled here, mixed market economies include those that fall clearly below the regression
line on the right hand side of Figure 1, i.e. Spain, Portugal, Italy and France.
36
In Table 8, the cells for the 1980s reveal substantial differences between CMEs and
LMEs of the sort associated with different types of coordination. Of most interest
here, however, are the changes that took place from the 1980s to the 1990s. Is there a
narrowing in the differences between LMEs and CMEs of the sort that might reflect
institutional convergence? In the realm of social protection, differences between the
two types of economies remain pronounced. Most striking is the increase in benefit
entitlements in CMEs compared to a slight decline in LMEs, suggesting that the latter
sharpened market mechanisms, while the former tended to cushion citizens against
the effects of market adjustment, moving more slowly to make changes to social protection even though we can expect some reductions in the coming years. In the labor
market, increases in part-time employment indicate a movement toward greater flexibility across all nations, but increasing cross-national divergence in levels of income
inequality and average annual hours worked per person in employment suggest different adjustment strategies across economies, at least in this initial period of adjustment.
Especially interesting are indicators for the institutional practices associated with firm
strategy and finance. Here, much has been made of recent changes in CMEs that seem
to reflect convergence on the practices of LMEs. However, these figures tell a more
nuanced story. In CMEs, the compensation of chief executive officers and the size of
stock markets have increased, taking the figures for the 1990s to levels characteristic of
LMEs during the 1980s undoubtedly changes of significance. But the analogous increases in LMEs have been substantially greater, leaving significant gaps between the
two types of economies on indicators of institutional practices, apparent in the debtto-equity ratios of nonfinancial enterprises, despite modest convergence there.
The figures for earnings and employment tell a classic story of the different adjustment paths followed by CMEs and LMEs. Strategically-coordinated wage bargaining
systems push real earnings up steadily in CMEs, while market-led adjustment induces
some decline in LMEs. But effective forms of coordination in the workplace and high
levels of investment keep the increase in unit labor costs in CMEs below that of LMEs.
However, the price paid for labor-saving investment and high real wages is a smaller
increase in employment in CMEs compared with LMEs.
On balance, we read these figures as an indication that institutional practices did not
converge dramatically across political economies during the 1980s and 1990s. CMEs
made modest efforts to improve flexibility, liberalizing some markets, and the institutions supporting strategic coordination there have undergone some changes. No
doubt, there will be further reforms in the coming years. But the absence of wholesale
convergence in the face of the substantial economic pressures experienced during the
1980s and 1990s suggests that the distinctions drawn by the varieties of capitalism
literature between different types of political economies are likely to be relevant for
some time to come.
37
Conclusion
We entered this project uncertain about whether we could find indicators for the relevant variables and what the tests of the hypotheses would reveal. We leave it impressed with the uniformity of the results. The weight of the evidence suggests that the
varieties of capitalism literature has identified important differences among political
economies. In the spheres of labor relations and corporate governance, there are systematic differences among nations that correspond well to the underlying dimension
of market-oriented versus strategic coordination that lies at the heart of the varieties
of capitalism approach. The contention that institutional complementarities operate
across these two spheres of the political economy is also borne out by the evidence.
The persistence of cross-national differences in institutional practices in the face of
intense pressures for convergence suggests that, despite some liberalization, the distinctions central to the varieties of capitalism approach are likely to be of continuing
importance.
Our findings about complementarities have especially important implications for
reform proposals now being considered in many nations. Proposals to deregulate labor markets have become increasingly popular in the developed world. However, our
evidence suggests that labor-market deregulation is likely to produce large economic
gains only in nations where financial markets are similarly fluid (see Table 5). Otherwise, the growth effects are relatively small. Similarly, many nations have come under
increasing pressure from international agencies or global financial actors to expand
equity markets and enhance competition in markets for corporate governance. However, these estimates suggest that, in the developed economies, such steps may have
only small positive effects on growth and ones that are available only where labor
markets are also highly fluid. Where labor market institutions are not so marketoriented, the effects on economic growth of deregulating corporate governance may
be deleterious.
The broader lesson here is that those seeking to understand the economic impact of
institutions should pay careful attention to the potential for institutional complementarities across spheres of the political economy. Most proposals to reform labor or
capital markets are based on econometric estimates about the effects of reform that
consider historical data only for the sphere being reformed. If the distribution of institutions across national cases is random, cross-national studies of this sort can produce
accurate results. But our evidence indicates that this distribution is far from random:
nations with particular types of institutions in one sphere tend to have particular types
of institutions in other spheres, as a varieties of capitalism analysis predicts. As a result, models that do not take interaction effects across institutional spheres into account may attribute to one set of institutions effects that are actually generated by
interaction among several sets of institutions.
38
Accordingly, these results set a research agenda, but they do not leave it entirely open:
ours is not a counsel of despair that finds complementarities everywhere. Although
there are undoubtedly more complementarities in the political economy than we have
examined, the varieties of capitalism literature specifies some precise complementarities that can be explored in more detail. The range of institutional indicators available
for doing so is expanding, and our results indicate that such analyses can be fruitful
(cf. Amable et al. 2000; Ernst 2002; Nicoletti et al. 2000; La Porta et al. 1998a; Kenworthy 1995).
In the most general terms, this analysis lends empirical weight to the theoretical perspective advanced by the varieties of capitalism literature. It suggests that a varieties of
capitalism approach to comparative capitalism need not be pertinent only to relatively
pure types of LMEs or CMEs but that the types of institutional differences to which it
draws our attention, based on the concepts of market-oriented and strategic coordination, are central to the operation of many developed political economies. This analytical framework can be used to locate many nations vis--vis one another and it yields
important insights about their economic performance.
39
References
Albert, Michel, 1993: Capitalism Against Capitalism. London: Whurr.
Alt, James, et al., 1996: The Political Economy of International Trade Enduring Puzzles and an
Agenda for Inquiry. In: Comparative Political Studies 29(6), 689717.
Alvarez, Michael /Geoffrey Garrett/ Peter Lange, 1991: Government Partisanship, Labor Organization and Macroeconomic Performance. In: American Political Science Review 85(2), 539556.
Amable, Bruno, 2000: Institutional Complementarity and Diversity of Social Systems of Innovation and Production. In: Review of International Political Economy 7(4), 645687.
Amable, Bruno/Ekkehard C. Ernst/Stefano Palombarini, 2001: How Do Financial Markets Affect
Industrial Relations: An Institutional Complementarity Approach. Unpublished Manuscript.
Paris: CEPREMAP.
Aoki, Masahiko, 1990: Toward an Economic Model of the Japanese Firm. In: Journal of Economic
Literature 28, 127.
, 1994: The Japanese Firm as a System of Attributes: A Survey and Research Agenda. In: Masahiko Aoki/Ronald Dore (eds.), The Japanese Firm: Sources of Competitive Strength. Oxford:
Oxford University Press, 1140.
Beck, Nathaniel /Jonathan Katz, 1995: What to Do (And Not to Do) with Time-Series CrossSection Data. In: American Political Science Review 89, 634648.
Berger, Suzanne /Ronald Dore (eds.), 1996: National Diversity and Global Capitalism. Ithaca: Cornell University Press.
Boyer, Robert, 1989: The Regulation School: A Critical Introduction. New York: Columbia University Press.
Breusch, Trevor / Adrian Pagan, 1980: The LaGrange Multiplier Test and Its Applications to
Model-Specification in Econometrics. In: Review of Economic Studies 47, 239253.
Caballero, Ricardo/Mohamad Hamour, 1998: The Macroeconomics of Specificity. In: Journal of
Political Economy 106, 724767.
Calmfors, Lars/John Driffill, 1988: Bargaining Structure, Corporatism and Macroeconomic Performance. In: Economic Policy, Issue 6, 1361.
Cameron, David, 1984: Social Democracy, Corporatism, Labor Quiescence and the Representation
of Economic Interest in Advanced Capitalist Society. In: John H. Goldthorpe (ed.), Order and
Conflict in Contemporary Capitalism. Oxford: Clarendon Press, 143178.
Campbell, John L. /J. Rogers Hollingsworth /Leon N. Lindberg, 1991: Governance of the American
Economy. New York: Cambridge University Press.
Carlin, Wendy/ Colin Mayer, 1999: Finance, Investment and Growth. CEPR discussion paper 2233.
London: Centre for Economic Policy Research.
, 2000: How Do Financial Systems Affect Economic Performance? In: Xavier Vives (ed.), Corporate Governance: Theoretical and Empirical Perspectives. Cambridge: Cambridge University
Press, 137160.
Casper, Steven, 1999: High Technology Governance and Institutional Adaptiveness. Discussion Paper
FS I 99307. Berlin: Wissenschaftszentrum Berlin fr Sozialforschung.
, 2001: The Legal Framework for Corporate Governance: Contract Law and Company Strategies in Germany and the United States. In: Peter A. Hall/ David Soskice (eds.), Varieties of
Capitalism: The Institutional Foundations of Comparative Advantage. Oxford: Oxford University Press, 387416.
Central Statistical Office 1991, 1999: Employment Gazette. London: HMSO (Her Majestys Stationery Office).
Cohen, Eli, 1989: LEtat Brancardier. Paris: Calmann-Levy.
Cox, Andrew, 1986: The State, Finance and Industry. Brighton: Wheatsheaf.
Crouch, Colin /Alessandro Pizzorno (eds.), 1978: The Resurgence of Class Conflict in Western
Europe since 1968, Vol. 1: National Studies. London: Macmillan.
Crouch, Colin/Wolfgang Streeck (eds.), 1997: The Political Economy of Modern Capitalism: Mapping Convergence and Diversity. London: Sage.
40
41
42
43
Soskice, David, 1990a: Wage Determination: The Changing Role of Institutions in Advanced Industrialized Countries. In: Oxford Review of Economic Policy 6(4), 3661.
, 1990b: Reinterpreting Corporatism and Explaining Unemployment: Coordinated and Noncoordinated Market Economies. In: Renato Brunetta / Carlo DellAringa (eds.), Labour Relations and Economic Performance. London: Macmillan, 170214.
, 1991: The Institutional Infrastructure for International Competitiveness: A Comparative
Analysis of the UK and Germany. In: Anthony B. Atkinson/Renato Brunetta (eds.), The Economics of the New Europe. London: Macmillan, 4566.
, 1994: Innovation Strategies of Companies: A Comparative Institutional Analysis of Some
Cross-Country Differences. In: Wolfgang Zapf /Meinolf Dierkes (eds.), Institutionenvergleich
und Institutionendynamik. Berlin: edition sigma, 271289.
, 1999: Divergent Production Regimes: Coordinated and Uncoordinated Market Economies in
the 1980s and 1990s. In: Herbert Kitschelt et al. (eds.), Continuity and Change in Contemporary Capitalism. Cambridge: Cambridge University Press, 101134.
Soskice, David /Torben Iversen, 2000: The Non-Neutrality of Monetary Policy with Large Wage
and Price Setters. In: Quarterly Journal of Economics 115(1), 265284.
Streeck, Wolfgang, 1997: German Capitalism: Does It Exist? Can It Survive? In: Colin Crouch/
Wolfgang Streeck (eds.), Political Economy of Modern Capitalism. London: Sage, 3354.
Swenson, Peter, 1991: Bringing Capital Back In. Social Democracy Reconsidered: Employer Power,
Cross-Class Alliances and Centralization of Industrial Relations in Denmark and Sweden. In:
World Politics 43(4), 513544.
, 1997: Arranged Alliances: Business Interests in the New Deal. In: Politics and Society 25, 66
116.
Teubner, Gunther, 2001: Legal Irritants. How Unifying Law Ends Up in New Divergences. In: Peter
A. Hall/David Soskice (eds.), Varieties of Capitalism: The Institutional Foundations of Comparative Advantage. Oxford: Oxford University Press, 417441.
Thelen, Kathleen, 1999: Why German Employers Cannot Bring Themselves to Dismantle the German Model. In: Torben Iversen / Jonas Pontusson /David Soskice (eds.), Unions, Employers
and Central Banks. New York: Cambridge University Press, 138172.
, 2001: Varieties of Labor Politics in the Developed Democracies. In: Peter A. Hall/ David
Soskice (eds.), Varieties of Capitalism: The Institutional Foundations of Comparative Advantage.
Oxford: Oxford University Press, 71103.
Thelen, Kathleen /Ikuo Kume, 1999: The Effects of Globalization on Labor Revisited: Lessons from
Germany and Japan. In: Politics and Society 27, 477505.
Traxler, Franz / Sabine Blaschke /Bernhard Kittel, 2000: National Labour Relations in Internationalized Markets. Oxford: Oxford University Press.
United Nations, 1999: Statistical Yearbook. New York: United Nations.
Verdier, Daniel, 2000: Social Against Mobile Capital: Explaining Cross-National Variation in Stock
Markets in the OECD. Conference paper. American Political Science Association Annual
Meeting, Washington, DC, 31 August3 September 2000.
Wallerstein, Michael, 1999: Wage-Setting Institutions and Pay Inequality in Advanced Industrial
Societies. In: American Journal of Political Science 43(3), 649680.
Whitley, Richard, 1999: Divergent Capitalisms: The Social Structuring of Business Systems. Oxford:
Oxford University Press.
Windolf, Paul, 2002: Corporate Networks in Europe and the United States. Oxford: Oxford University Press.
Wood, Stewart, 2001: Business, Government, and Patterns of Labor Market Policy in Britain and
the Federal Republic of Germany. In: Peter A. Hall/David Soskice (eds.), Varieties of Capitalism: The Institutional Foundations of Comparative Advantage. Oxford: Oxford University
Press, 247274.
Zysman, John, 1983: Governments, Markets and Growth. Ithaca: Cornell University Press.
MPIfG Books
DP 04 / 4
R. Mayntz
Organizational Forms of
Terrorism: Hierarchy, Network,
or a Type sui generis?
WP 04 / 3
P. Manow
'The Good, the Bad, and the
Ugly' Esping-Andersen's
Regime Typology and the
Religious Roots of the Western
Welfare State
DP 04 / 3
C. Trampusch
Von Verbnden zu Parteien
Der Elitenwechsel in der
Sozialpolitik
DP 04 / 2
E. Seils
The Effects of Fiscal Contracts:
Financial Policy in the
Netherlands 19772002
DP 04 / 1
S. Burkhart
Parteipolitikverflechtung: Der
Einfluss der Bundespolitik auf
Landtagswahlentscheidungen
von 1976 bis 2002
DP 03 / 8
R. Werle
Institutionalistische
Technikanalyse: Stand
und Perspektiven
DP 03 / 7
S. Ltz
Convergence within National
Diversity: A Comparative
Perspective on the Regulatory
State in Finance
WP 04 / 2
F. W. Scharpf
Der deutsche Fderalismus
reformbedrftig und
reformierbar?
WP 04 / 1
R. Mayntz
Governance Theory als
fortentwickelte
Steuerungstheorie?
WP 03 / 12
M. Heipertz, A. Verdun
The Dog that Would Never
Bite? The Past and Future
of the Stability and Growth
Pact
WP 03 / 11
S. Ganghof, T. Bruninger
Partisan Veto Players in
Australia, Denmark, Finland
and Germany: Government
Status and Legislative Behavior
Ordering Information
MPIfG Discussion Papers
Order printed copies from the MPIfG (you will be
billed) or download PDF file from the MPIfG website (free).
MPIfG Working Papers
Onlineat the MPIfG website.
MPIfG Books
At bookstores; abstracts on the MPIfG website.
www.mpifg.de
Go to Publications.
S. Ganghof
Wer regiert in der
Steuerpolitik?
Einkommensteuerreform
zwischen internationalem
Wettbewerb und nationalen
Verteilungskonflikten
Campus 2004
H. Enderlein
Nationale Wirtschaftspolitik in
der europischen
Whrungsunion
Campus 2004
C. Crouch, P. Le Gals, C.
Trigilia, and H. Voelzkow (eds.)
Changing Governance of Local
Economies. Responses of
European Local Production
Systems
Oxford University Press 2004
H. Kitschelt, W. Streeck (eds.)
Germany: Beyond the
Stable State
Frank Cass 2004
New Titles
Consult our website for the most complete and upto-date information about MPIfG publications and
publications by MPIfG researchers. To sign up for
newsletters and mailings, please go to Service on the
MPIfG website. Upon request to [email protected], we
will be happy to send you our Recent Publications
brochure.
ERPA
MPIfG Discussion Papers and MPIfG Working Papers
in the field of European integration research are
included in the European Research Papers Archive
(ERPA) which offers full-text search options:
http://eiop.or.at/erpa.