Jaae 363
Jaae 363
Over the recent past, food prices increased dramatically, leading to much debate about the end
of cheap food period. This type of food crisis
has serious implications for ecological sustainability, for the role of international financial institutions, and for the risk of future nutritional
emergencies. In rich countries, food covers a
relatively small part of a households budget; by
contrast, in poor countries, households use a
large share of their income for food expenses,
implying that food price increases lead to reduced real income as well as to higher risks of
96
97
98
(positively) crucial in the Greek economy following the Maastricht Treaty. Varangis (1992),
through the methodology of Autoregressive Conditional Heteroscedasticity (ARCH) models, finds
that money supply developments strongly affect
the volatility of food prices. Maravegias (1997)
argues that the manner in which the exchange
rate policy has been implemented, relative to the
evolution of the general price index, seems to
have had a direct effect on the prices Greek
farmers received. At the same time, the efforts of
Greek policymakers since the mid-1980s to reduce substantially high inflationthrough the
implementation of a strict monetary policy that
led to high interest rateshave also exerted a
substantial impact on food prices (Maravegias,
1997). Zanias (1998) identifies a role for macroeconomic factors that seems to have a substantial
impact on Greek inflation, which, in turn, alters
food prices. He claims that macroeconomic instability contributes to higher food price volatility,
which in turn has adverse effects on agricultural
production and income. Finally, Hondroyiannis
and Papapetrou (1998) examine the relation
between money supply and agricultural prices
over the period 19721994. Their results show
that money supply changes can affect agricultural prices through the mechanism of interest
rates.
The objective of this article is to investigate
the manner short-run deviations from the relationship between food prices and macroeconomic factors that drive food price volatility in
Greece. Therefore, when volatility is increased
as a result of shocks in the system, it is reasonable to investigate the behavior of conditional
variance as a function of short-run deviations
from the equilibrium path. The accurate measurement of food price volatility is important
not only because volatility causes uncertainty to
producers, consumers, and policymakers, but
also costs are inevitably incurred (McMillan,
2003). A significant positive effect would imply
that short-run deviations affect not only the conditional mean, but also the conditional variance,
implying that the further food prices deviate from
macroeconomic variables in the short run, the
harder they are to predict. In other words, conditional heteroscedasticity could be modeled as a
function of lagged error correction terms affected
99
The remaining text of this article is organized as follows. The next section describes
the methodology used, whereas the following
section presents the empirical analysis and
discusses the empirical results. The final section concludes the article.
The Methodology of GARCH and
GARCH-X Models
The ARCH methodology, pioneered by Engle
(1982), suggests a method for measuring uncertainty if it is serially correlated. The empirical
methodology used here extends the ARCH model.
Let xt be a models prediction error, b a vector
of parameters, and xt a vector of predetermined
explanatory variables in the equation for the conditional mean:
(1)
yt 5 xt b 1 xt
xt jWt1 ; N0,ht
ht 5 u0 1
p
X
i51
ci hti 1
q
X
aj x2 ti
j51
100
ht 5 u0 1
p
X
ci hti 1
i51
q
X
aj x2 ti 1 g 1 z2 t1
j51
divided by the population index,1 the real exchange rate (RE) measured as the real effective
exchange rate index (1995 5 100), and the budget
deficit (or surplus) to income ratio (DEFY). The
effective exchange rate is defined in such a manner as a decline in the ratio to be consistent with a
real appreciation of the domestic currency. Deficit, money supply, and food prices are divided
by the Gross Domestic Product deflator. In this
manner, the real deficit to income ratio (RDEFY),
real money balances (RM), and relative food
prices (PP), respectively, are obtained. Data
span the period 19852007 and are obtained
(except that on food prices) from the Research
Department of the Bank of Greece. Food prices
are described as an index of producer prices of
agricultural products (1995 5 100) and they are
obtained from the Eurostat NewCronos database. Note that an index of producer prices received by farmers for food items is not available
for the period under consideration, whereas a
price index was necessary to capture the price
behavior of the whole food sector. Moreover, a
price index at the producer price level was used
and at the consumer price level because the former does not include imports.
The period coincides with the period in
which Greece has been a full member of the EU
(European Economic Community), whereas important economic policy incidents occurred. For
empirical purposes of the study, a dummy variable is considered that is related to the reforms
adopted with respect to the implementation of the
CAP that occurred in May 1992. The reform of
the CAP decreased price support for farmers and
increased direct income support. As Ray et al.
(1998) argue, however, our data set cannot be
used to determine the portion of price variability
that could be attributed to the CAP reform and
policy changes instituted in the 1992 CAP Treaty.
The original data are seasonally unadjusted.
However, a certain number of researchers have
Data
The empirical analysis is carried out using
monthly data on food prices proxied by producer
prices (prices received by farmers), money supply defined as M1, income per capita (YPOP)
defined as the ratio of industrial production index
1 The per-capita GDP or GNP for Greece is available on an annual or quarterly basis. In the present
article, we used monthly data to estimate the proposed
models. To this end, we used the industrial production
index instead of the per capita GDP or GNP, which is
available on a monthly basis. The share of industrial
sector in GDP of Greece is approximately 20.3%.
101
power, especially in small samples. Thus, to increase the power of our unit, root results alternative tests are also used such as the Kwiatkowski
et al. (KPSS, 1992) test in which stationarity is
the null rather than the alternative hypothesis.
These results are also reported in Table 1. The
102
Rm
re
ypop
pp
Significant at 5%.
Without Trend
Levels
21.83
22.44
22.03
22.17
22.42
With Trend
First Differences
28.30
25.25
26.38
210.51
210.28
(5)
(7)
(4)
(6)
(3)
(4)a
(4)a
(3)a
(3)a
(2)a
Level Stationarity
1.1983
1.1864
1.1481
1.1184
1.1095
1.1766
1.1468
1.1235
1.0842
1.0655
1.2347
1.2094
1.1541
1.1288
1.1036
1.1847
1.1437
1.1153
1.0964
1.0655
1.2095
1.1764
1.1533
1.1239
1.1052
(l
(l
(l
(l
(l
(l
(l
(l
(l
(l
(l
(l
(l
(l
(l
(l
(l
(l
(l
(l
(l
(l
(l
(l
(l
5
5
5
5
5
5
5
5
5
5
5
5
5
5
5
5
5
5
5
5
5
5
5
5
5
Levels
21.14
20.73
22.16
21.94
22.39
First Differences
20.79
20.64
21.16
21.22
21.38
(5)
(7)
(4)
(6)
(3)
0)
1)
2)
3)
4)
0)
1)
2)
3)
4)
0)
1)
2)
3)
4)
0)
1)
2)
3)
4)
0)
1)
2)
3)
4)
1.3471
1.3277
1.2352
1.1684
1.1172
1.2527
1.2239
1.1540
1.1236
1.1093
1.3544
1.3093
1.2422
1.1981
1.1535
1.2236
1.1874
1.1346
1.1058
1.0861
1.2879
1.2252
1.1879
1.1456
1.1233
(l
(l
(l
(l
(l
(l
(l
(l
(l
(l
(l
(l
(l
(l
(l
(l
(l
(l
(l
(l
(l
(l
(l
(l
(l
5
5
5
5
5
5
5
5
5
5
5
5
5
5
5
5
5
5
5
5
5
5
5
5
5
21.13
20.86
21.41
21.68
21.82
(5)
(7)
(4)
(6)
(3)
First Differences
a
23.79 (4)
23.11 (4)a
24.57 (3)a
24.66 (3)a
23.93 (2)a
Levels
21.25
20.96
21.47
21.71
21.82
(5)
(6)
(7)
(6)
(4)
First Differences
24.15
23.69
24.77
24.80
24.38
(4)a
(5)a
(4)a
(4)a
(3)a
With Trend
First Differences
24.33
23.58
24.83
24.92
24.29
0)
1)
2)
3)
4)
0)
1)
2)
3)
4)
0)
1)
2)
3)
4)
0)
1)
2)
3)
4)
0)
1)
2)
3)
4)
With Trend
Without Trend
Levels
(4)a
(5)a
(4)a
(4)a
(3)a
Trend Stationarity
Without Trend
Levels
28.42
25.76
26.44
28.87
27.21
(5)
(6)
(7)
(6)
(4)
(4)a
(4)a
(3)a
(3)a
(2)a
Levels
21.52
21.07
21.36
21.95
21.99
(5)
(6)
(7)
(6)
(4)
First Differences
24.72
24.13
25.66
25.38
24.68
(4)a
(5)a
(4)a
(4)a
(3)a
103
n-r
r
r
r
r
r
5
5
5
5
5
1
2
3
4
5
m.l.
95%
Tr
95%
42.8940
29.2280
12.5041
8.5881
3.0285
37.0700
31.0000
24.3500
18.3300
11.5400
96.2427
53.3487
24.1207
11.6166
3.0285
82.2300
58.9300
39.3300
23.8300
11.5400
32.47
4.58
1.39
0.95
0.27
[0.026]
[0.197]
[0.304]
[0.426]
[0.587]
r, number of cointegrating vectors; n-r, number of common trends; m.l., maximum eigenvalue statistic; Tr, Trace statistic. Figures
in brackets denote p values. The number of lags was determined through Likelihood Ratio tests developed by Sims (1980).
and RESET is a model specification test. Numbers in parentheses denote p values. Both tests
identify the adequacy of our model.
However, in May 1992, critical changes
occurred in the CAP implementation. Thus, a
dummy variable (with values of zero up to 1992:4
and one thereafter) that captures the restructuring
conditions of this CAP policy change is also considered in the cointegrating vector. The Saikkonen
and Lutkepohl (2000) test with a break at 1992:4 is
used to test for any possible break shift of the
cointegration vector. This test rejects the null
hypothesis of no cointegration. The results of
this test incorporating this shift are also reported
in Table 2. These findings also provide evidence
in favor of cointegration between the variables
under study. The new cointegration vector yields:
104
Dpp 5 0:389 Dpp4 1 0:12 Dpp5 1 0:212 Dpp8 1 0:494 DRDEFY1 0:0392 DRDEFY2
5:54*
2:77*
2:93*
4:61*
3:07*
1 0:0231DRDEFY3 0.151 Drm4 1 0:168 Dre8 1 0:078Dypop3 1 0:072 Dypop4
2:17*
3:57*
3:82*
2:15*
3:01*
1 0:236 Dypop6 1 0:154 Dypop7 1 0:094 Dypop8 0:418 EC1 0:19 CAP
6:29*
3:94*
3:47*
5:02*
2:86*
the short
the CAP
to render
internal
run. These
reform led
them more
and world
The estimated model satisfies certain diagnostics such as absence of serial correlation
(LM), absence of misspecification (RESET),
presence of normality (NO), and absence of
heteroscedasticity (HE). However, it suffers
from the presence of ARCH effects, even at the
first lag. The ARCH tests indicate the presence
of volatility clustering in relative food prices.
They suggest the use of the GARCH methodology as the appropriate approach to generate
both consistent estimates of the mean equation
and to describe the evolution of the variance of
relative food prices.
105
Dpp 5 0:306 Dpp4 1 0:123 Dpp5 1 0:045 Dpp8 1 0:424 DRDEFY1 0.0399 DRDEFY2
2.56*
3.32*
2.18*
4.96*
3.97*
1 0:0298 DRDEFY30:148 Drm4 1 0.283Dre8 1 0:168Dypop3 1 0:056Dypop4
4:59*
5:96*
5:05*
3:08*
5:99*
1 0:279 Dypop6 1 0:209 Dypop7 1 0:129 Dypop8 0:131 EC1 0:205 CAP
5.03*
3.34*
4.89*
xti2
5.12*
3.97*
1 0:0806 ECt12
10:5*
106
The exponential nature of the EGARCH ensures that the conditional variance is always
positive even if the parameter values are negative; thus, there is no need for parameter restrictions to impose nonnegativity. The parameter
g captures the asymmetric effect, whereas the
parameter b captures persistence. The model is
estimated using the robust method of BollerslevWooldridges quasimaximum likelihood estimator assuming the Gaussian standard normal
distribution. The results yield:
Dpp 5 0:287 Dpp2 1 0:146 Dpp3 1 0:102 Dpp5 1 0:406 DRDEFY1 0.136 DRDEFY1
3.05*
3.61*
3.44*
3.87*
4.16*
1 0:095 DRDEFY2 0:155 Drm2 1 0.261Dre6 1 0:179Dypop2 1 0:135 Dypop2
4:16*
4:67*
4:67*
3:58*
5:47*
1 0:292 Dypop4 1 0:227 Dypop3 1 0:157 Dypop5 0:157 EC1 0:245 CAP
5.53
3.62*
4.36*
4.68*
4.26*
107
References
Apergis, N., and A. Rezitis. Food Price Volatility
and Macroeconomic Factor Volatility: Heat
Waves or Meteor Showers? Applied Economics Letters 10(2003):15560.
Attie, A.P., and S.K. Roache. Inflation Hedging
for Long-term Investors. IMF Working Paper
No. 09/90. Washington, DC: IMF, 2009.
Ball, L., and N.G. Mankiw. Relative Price
Change as Aggregate Supply Shocks. NBER
Working Paper No. 4168, 1992.
Barnett, R.C., D.A. Bessler, and R.L. Thompson.
The Money Supply and Nominal Agricultural
Prices. American Journal of Agricultural Economics 65(1983):303307.
Berndt, E.K., B.H. Hall, R.E. Hall, and J.A.
Hausman. Estimation and Inference in Nonlinear Structural Models. Annals of Economics and Social Measurement 4(1974):65365.
Bessler, D.A. Relative Prices and Money: A
Vector Autoregression on Brazilian Data.
American Journal of Agricultural Economics
66(1984):2530.
Blisard, N., and J.R. Blaylock. Estimating the Variance of Food Price Inflation. Journal of Agricultural and Applied Economics 25(1993):24552.
Bollerslev, T. Generalized Autoregressive Conditional Heteroscedasticity. Journal of Econometrics 31(1986):30727.
Calvo, G. Exploding Commodity Prices, Lax
Monetary Policy, and Sovereign Wealth Funds.
2008. Internet site: http://voxeu.org/index.php?
q5node/1244.
Campiche, J., H. Bryant, J. Richardson, and J.
Outlaw. Examining the Evolving Correspondence between Petroleum Prices and Agricultural Commodity Prices. Paper presented at
the American Agricultural Economic Association Meeting, Portland, OR, July 29 to August
1, 2007.
108
109
110