The Dynamics of Leveraged and Inverse Exchange-Traded Funds
The Dynamics of Leveraged and Inverse Exchange-Traded Funds
Exchange-Traded Funds
Minder Cheng and Ananth Madhavan
Barclays Global Investors
May 9, 2009
Abstract
Leveraged and inverse Exchange-Traded Funds (ETFs) have attracted significant assets
lately. Unlike traditional ETFs, these funds have “leverage” explicitly embedded as part
of their product design. While these funds are primarily used by short-term traders, they
are gaining popularity with individual investors placing leveraged bets or hedging their
portfolios. The structure of these funds, however, creates both intended and unintended
characteristics that are not seen in traditional ETFs. This note provides a unified
framework to better understand the underlying dynamics of leveraged and inverse ETFs,
their impact on market volatility and liquidity, unusual features of their product design,
and questions of investor suitability. We show that the daily re-leveraging of these funds
can exacerbate volatility towards the close. We also show that the gross return of a
leveraged or inverse ETF has an embedded path-dependent option that under certain
conditions can lead to value destruction for a buy-and-hold investor. The unsuitability
of these products for longer-term investors is reinforced by the drag on returns from
high transaction costs and tax inefficiency.†
1 Introduction
Leveraged and inverse Exchange-Traded Funds (ETFs) provide leveraged long or short
exposure to the daily return of various indexes, sectors, and asset classes. These funds
have “leverage” explicitly embedded as part of their product design. The category has
exploded since the first products were introduced in 2006, especially in volatile sectors such
as Financials, Real Estate, and Energy. As of end-January 2009, there are now over 106
leveraged and inverse ETFs in the US alone with Assets Under Management (AUM) of
about $22 billion.1
†
The views expressed here are those of the authors alone and not necessarily those of Barclays Global
Investors, its officers or directors. This note is intended to stimulate further research and is not a recom-
mendation of any particular securities or investment strategy. We thank Mark Coppejans, Matt Goff, Allan
Lane, Hayne Leland, J. Parsons, Heather Pelant, Ira Shapiro, Mike Sobel, Richard Tsai and an anonymous
referee for their helpful comments.
c 2009, Barclays Global Investors. All rights reserved.
1
This figure does not include leveraged mutual funds that have the same characteristics as leveraged
ETFs except for the fact that they are not traded intradaily.
1
Dynamics of Leveraged and Inverse ETFs 2
The space now comprises leveraged, inverse, and leveraged inverse ETFs offering 2× or
3× long exposure or short exposure of −1×, −2×, or −3× the underlying index returns. The
most recent products authorized by the US Securities and Exchange Commission (SEC) offer
the highest leverage factors. However, the bulk of AUM remains in 2× leveraged products.
Coverage has also expanded beyond equities and includes commodities, fixed income and
foreign exchange. There is strong growth in this space outside the US as well. In addition,
option contracts on leveraged ETFs have also gained in popularity. Leveraged and inverse
mutual funds analogous to ETFs have also grown in popularity. Other than the fact that
they offer investors liquidity at only one point in the day, the structure of these products is
identical to leveraged and inverse ETFs and hence our analysis is fully applicable to these
funds too.
Several factors explain the attraction of leveraged and inverse ETFs. First, these funds
offer short-term traders and hedge funds a structured product to express their directional
views regarding a wide variety of equity indexes and sectors. Second, as investors can obtain
levered exposure within the product, they need not rely on increasingly scarce outside
capital or the use of derivatives, swaps, options, futures, or trading on margin. Third,
individual investors – attracted by convenience and limited liability nature of these products
– increasingly use them to place longer-term leveraged bets or to hedge their portfolios.
The structure of these funds, however, creates both intended and unintended character-
istics. Indeed, despite their popularity, many of the features of these funds are not fully
understood, even among professional asset managers and traders. This paper provides a
unified framework to better understand some key aspects of these leveraged and inverse
ETFs, including their underlying dynamics, unusual features of their product design, their
impact on financial market microstructure, and questions of investor suitability.
Specifically, leveraged ETFs must re-balance their exposures on a daily basis to produce
the promised leveraged returns. What may seem counterintuitive is that irrespective of
whether the ETFs are leveraged, inverse or leveraged inverse, their re-balancing activity
is always in the same direction as the underlying index’s daily performance. The hedging
flows from equivalent long and short leveraged ETFs thus do not “offset” each other. The
magnitude of the potential impact is proportional to the amount of assets gathered by
these ETFs, the leveraged multiple promised, and the underlying index’s daily returns.
The impact is particularly significant for inverse ETFs. For example, a double-inverse ETF
promising −2× the index return requires a hedge equal to 6× the day’s change in the fund’s
Net Asset Value (NAV), whereas a double-leveraged ETF requires only 2× the day’s change.
This daily re-leveraging has profound microstructure effects, exacerbating the volatility of
the underlying index and the securities comprising the index.
While a leveraged or inverse ETF replicates a multiple of the underlying index’s return
on a daily basis, the gross return of these funds over a finite time period can be shown to
have an embedded path-dependent option on the underlying index. We show that leveraged
and inverse ETFs are not suitable for buy-and-hold investors because under certain circum-
stances the long-run returns can be significantly below that of the appropriately levered
underlying index. This is particularly true for volatile indexes and for inverse ETFs. The
unsuitability of these products for longer-term investors is reinforced by tax inefficiency and
the cumulative drag on returns from transaction costs related to daily re-balancing activity.
The paper proceeds as follows: Section 2 shows how leveraged and inverse ETF returns
Dynamics of Leveraged and Inverse ETFs 3
are related to those of the underlying index and provides an overview of the mechanics of the
implied hedging demands resulting from the daily re-leveraging of these products; Section
3 explains the microstructure implications and resulting return drag from trading costs
associated with hedging activity; Section 4 analyzes the longer-term return characteristics
of these products and the value of the embedded option within; and Section 5 summarizes
our results and discusses their implications for public policy.
We will assume there are no dividends throughout to focus on the price and return dynamics
without any loss of generality. Let x represent the leveraged multiple of a leveraged or inverse
ETF. Therefore x = −2, -1, 2 and 3 correspond to double-inverse, inverse, double-leveraged
and triple-leveraged ETFs.
ΠN
n=1 (1 + x rtn−1 , tn ) (2)
that have a very different relationship to the longer-term returns of the underlying index
leveraged statically, as given by:
(1 + x rt0 , tN ) (3)
We can use a double-leveraged ETF (x = 2) with an initial NAV of $100 as an example. It
tracks an index that starts at 100, falls 10% one day and then goes up 10% the subsequent
day. Over the two-day period, the index declines by -1% (down to 90, and then climbing
to 99). While an investor might expect the leveraged fund to decline by twice as much,
or -2%, over the two-day period, it actually declines further, by -4%. Why? Doubling the
index’s 10% fall on the first day pushes the fund’s NAV to $80. The next day, the fund’s
NAV climbs to $96 upon doubling the index’s 10% gain. This example illustrates the path
dependency of leveraged ETF returns, a topic we return to more formally when we model
the continuous time evolution of asset prices in section 4.
Dynamics of Leveraged and Inverse ETFs 5
Let Atn represent a leveraged or inverse ETF’s NAV at the close of day n or at time
tn . Corresponding to Atn , let Ltn represent the notional amount of the total return swaps
exposure that is required before the market opens on the next day to replicate the intended
leveraged return of the index for the fund from calendar time tn to time tn+1 . With the
fund’s NAV at Atn at time tn , the notional amount of the total return swaps required is
given by:
Ltn = x Atn (4)
On day n + 1, the underlying index generates a return of rtn , tn+1 and the exposure of the
total return swaps, denoted by Etn+1 , becomes:
At the same time, reflecting the gain or loss that is x times the index’s performance between
tn and tn+1 , the leveraged fund’s NAV at the close of day n + 1 becomes:
which suggests that the notional amount of the total return swaps this is required before
the market opens next day to maintain constant exposure is:
The difference between (6) and (9), denoted by ∆tn+1 , is the amount by which the exposure
of the total return swaps that need to be adjusted or re-hedged at time tn+1 , as given by:
Table 2: Dynamics of an inverse ETF (x = −1, rt0 , t1 = −10% and rt1 , t2 = 10%)
when the funds are not leveraged or inverse), the reset or re-balance flows are always in the
same direction as the underlying index’s performance. So, when the underlying index is
up, additional total return swap exposure must be added, but when the underlying index is
down, the exposure of total return swaps needs to be reduced. This is intuitively clear for
a leveraged long fund, is always true whether the ETFs are leveraged, inverse or leveraged
inverse. Why is the effect the same for funds that are short the index? Intuitively, an
inverse or leveraged inverse fund’s NAV will increase if the index falls, which requires it to
increase short exposure still further, generating selling pressure. In other words, there is no
offset or “pairing off” of leveraged long and short ETFs on the same index, which is why the
re-balance flows are in the same direction between Table 1 for a double-leveraged ETF and
Tables 2 and 3 for an inverse and a double-inverse ETF on day 1 and day 2, respectively.
Note the need for daily re-hedging is unique to leveraged and inverse ETFs due to
their product design. Traditional ETFs that are not leveraged or inverse, whether they are
holding physicals, total return swaps or other derivatives, have no need to re-balance daily.
We discuss the implications of daily re-balances in the next section.
Table 3: Dynamics of a double-inverse ETF (x = −2, rt0 , t1 = −10% and rt1 , t2 = 10%)
inverse ETF re-balancing activity as a factor behind increased volatility at the close.5 Of
course, other factors might also account for heightened volatility at the close. For exam-
ple, traders might choose to trade later in the day because there are more macroeconomic
announcements earlier in the day or because the price discovery process takes longer. Nev-
ertheless, as we show in this section, there are good theoretical and empirical grounds to
support the argument that daily re-leveraging by leveraged and inverse ETFs contributes
to volatility.
In theory, re-balancing activity should be executed as near the market close as possi-
ble given the dependence of the re-balancing amount on the close-to-close return of the
underlying index as per (11). Whether leveraged and inverse ETFs re-balance their ex-
posure of total return swaps immediately before or after the market close, however, their
counterparties with which they execute total return swaps will very likely put on or adjust
their hedges while the market is still open to minimize the risk to their capital and position
taking. So, as leveraged and inverse ETFs gain assets, there likely will be a heightened
impact on the liquidity and volatility of the underlying index and the securities comprising
the index during the closing period (e.g., the last hour or half-hour) of the day’s trading
session.
The magnitude of the potential impact from re-balancing activity is proportional to
the amount of assets gathered by leveraged and inverse ETFs in aggregate, the leveraged
multiple promised by these funds, and the underlying index’s daily return. Such predictable
and concentrated trading activity near the market close may also create an environment for
“front running” and market manipulation.6 Merely substituting total return swaps with
alternative instruments such as trading in the physicals on margin, futures, equity-linked
notes or other derivatives will have the same economic impact as long as the product design
is based on taking leveraged positions in these instruments.
5
See, e.g., Lauricella, Pulliam, and Gullapalli (2008), who note: “As the market grew more volatile in
September, Wall Street proprietary trading desks began piling onto the back of the trade knowing that the
end-of-day ETF-related buying or selling was on its way. If the market was falling, they would buy a short
ETF and short the stocks or the market some other way. If the market was rallying, they would buy a bull
fund and go long.”
6
Illegal front running refers to a broker executing orders for its own account before filling pending client
orders that are likely to affect the security’s price. Here, we use the term more colloquially to refer to trading
ahead of the flows that are highly predictable given public information on index returns and fund AUM that
need not be illegal.
Dynamics of Leveraged and Inverse ETFs 9
Here λ > 0 is the price impact coefficient (which in turn can be thought of as an increasing
function of volatility and decreasing function of average daily volume), and qtn , tn+1 is the
signed order flow from market participants, excluding the hedging demand from leveraged
and inverse ETFs. The stochastic error term wtn , tn+1 captures the effect of unpredictable
news shocks or noise trading. The hedging demand itself depends on the day’s price change:
where we require that λ φ atn (x2 − x) < 1 for equilibrium to be defined. This expression
makes clear the magnified impact of hedging demands on overall price movements by in-
creasing the market impact coefficient for all flows, irrespective of their source. Intuitively,
hedging demand provides an additional momentum effect to same-day returns that increases
the price pressure effect of any signed order imbalance regardless of its source.
The price impact is greater with higher volatility, lower market liquidity, higher same-
day effects, increased AUM, and higher leverage ratios. The presence of the lagged hedge
term ∆tn−1 (when φ < 1) induces serial correlation in returns because the previous period’s
hedge is linearly related to the previous return. Thus, the analysis shows that hedging flows
in leveraged and inverse ETFs can exacerbate same-day volatility, add momentum effects,
and induce serial correlation in returns.
Figure 3: AUM in US Equity Leveraged and Inverse ETFs by Leverage Factor (x) - January
2009
on various US equity indexes including S&P 500, 400, and 600 indexes, Nasdaq QQQ,
Russell 1000, 2000, and various sub-indexes/sectors including Financials, Oil& Gas, Real
Estate, Materials, etc. This sample is largely the universe of domestic equity leveraged
funds, excluding commodity and currency leveraged funds. Ranked by notional value (as
of January 2009) the top three ETFs are the ProShares Ultra S&P 500 (SSO), UltraShort
S&P 500 (SDS), and the ProShares Ultra Financials (UYG) with notional AUM of $3.0
billion, $2.9 billion, and $1.7 billion, respectively. Also included are the new 3× and −3×
funds from Direxion covering the Russell 1000 (BGU and BGZ) and other indexes.
Figure 3 shows the percentage of AUM for the universe of US equity leveraged and
inverse ETFs, broken down by leverage factor (x = −3×, ..., 3×) for end-January, 2009. As
of end-January 2009, the sample comprises 84 equity leveraged and inverse ETFs with a
total of $19 billion in AUM, of which $1.4 billion or 7.3% has x = 3 or −3, a category that
did not exist in 2007.
For the above same 84 US equity leveraged and inverse ETFs, Table 4 reports details
on various statistics of interest by leverage factor (x = −3×, ..., 3×) as of January 2009.
Several points are worth noting. Although bid-ask spreads are reasonably small, their
economic impact is large given the short holding periods. Most transactions occur at or
within the quotes. Liquidity is generally good, especially in double-leveraged products,
where the ratio of depth (i.e., mean quote size in dollars) to order size (in dollars) is high.
Management fees and other costs are large relative to most traditional ETFs and do not
vary significantly by leverage. Average holding periods (calculated as the ratio of month-
end shares outstanding to average daily share volume for the month) are shortest for the
most levered products, but are still significant for double-leveraged ETFs (15.2 days) which
account for the bulk of AUM. Some of the most recent and active leveraged funds (e.g.,
Dynamics of Leveraged and Inverse ETFs 11
Table 4: Summary Statistics on US Equity Leveraged and Inverse ETFs (January, 2009)
Direxion Daily Financials -3× Bear (FAZ)) have holding periods as short as 0.2 of a trading
day. Note that these are averages over heterogeneous investor populations. It is quite likely
that holding periods vary by investor category. For example, sophisticated hedge funds may
employ leveraged ETFs for within day bets while retail investors may have longer holding
periods.
For each ETF, indexed by i = 1, ..., K, we compute the notional hedge as before and
hence the aggregate value of hedging demand at the end of day n can be expressed as a
function of the hypothetical return as ∆tn−1 (rtn−1 , tn ) where :
K
!
X
∆tn−1 (rtn−1 , tn ) = Ai, tn−1 (x2i − xi ) rtn−1 , tn (15)
i=1
where Ai, tn−1 is the AUM of ETF i at the close of day n − 1 or at time tn−1 .
The table below shows the function ∆tn−1 (rtn−1 , tn ) (in millions of dollars) for returns to
the corresponding stock indexes from 1% to +15% as of end February 2009. We assume that
all sub-indexes had the same return, which is an obvious simplification but not unreasonable
given the highly correlated nature of the current market. Also shown is the hedging demand
as a percentage of median market-on-close volume. We use the median as volume is heavily
skewed by end-of-month flows, quarterly re-balances, and option expiration cycles, but the
result is very similar if the mean were used instead. Note that since we are essentially
computing a weighted average, the market-on-close demand in value terms is just a linear
function of return. However, the demand as a fraction of closing volume is a non-linear
function of return because the re-balancing demand is added to the denominator too. So,
for example, a broad 1% move in the US equity market would result in additional MOC
demand of about 17%, while a 5% move is associated with demands equal to 50% of the
close.
As AUM changes and more levered and ultra short products gain traction, we would
expect this slope to steepen. Indeed, the amount of hedging has been increasing. Using each
ETF’s AUM for December 31, 2008 and December 31, 2007, we compute the end-of-day
dollar flows for a 5% return. This yields end-of-day flows of $3.5 and $2.1 billion, respec-
tively. Observe that the hedging demand corresponding to a 5% move has already risen to
Dynamics of Leveraged and Inverse ETFs 12
$3.9 billion, almost double from year-end 2007. These are likely conservative estimates as
we exclude re-balancing flows from leveraged and inverse mutual funds.
rt−
n , tn
= β0 + β1 rtn −1, tn + β2 ∆tn (16)
where t−n denotes the calendar time of 3 p.m. Eastern time on day n, rt− n , tn
is the intra-day
S&P 500 return from 3 p.m. Eastern time to the close on day n, rtn −1, tn is the close to
close S&P 500 return, and ∆tn is the signed aggregate re-balance flow (in billions of dollars).
Equation (16) has a straightforward economic interpretation: β1 captures the contribution
to the day’s return of the closing period. The coefficient β2 captures the additional impact
of re-balancing flows on market movements in the closing period over and above the daily
return movement.
The regression estimates yield β1 = 0.249 and β2 = 0.541 with t-statistics of 5.806
and 2.503, respectively, and R2 = 0.35 with 825 degrees of freedom. The coefficient β0 is
economically and statistically insignificant (0.01) as we would expect in a model of signed
returns without directional bias. The closing period is 15.4% of the total trading day, but is
a higher fraction (about 25%) of the day’s volume and hence of the day’s return as implied
by the estimates. The estimate of β2 suggests that after controlling for the day’s return
movement, $1 billion of re-balancing flow adds 0.54% to the closing period’s return.
Dynamics of Leveraged and Inverse ETFs 13
Since concerns about re-balancing flows are often framed in terms of volatility, we also
examine the second moment of closing period returns. Specifically, we want to see if there
is an empirical relation between absolute returns in the closing period and the magnitude
of re-balancing flows. It is possible that more volatile days will see greater movements at
the close, so we use the daily value of the VIX index as a control variable. Accordingly, we
run the following regression using daily data from January 1, 2006 to mid-April 2009:
|rt−
n , tn
| = β0 + β1 Vtn + β2 |∆tn | (17)
4 Return Dynamics
Having discussed the mechanics of leveraged and inverse ETFs and market structure im-
plications of daily re-balancing activity, we turn now to an analysis of returns over longer
periods of time. Our objective is to understand return dynamics and the role of the embed-
ded option within the leveraged and inverse product to address questions concerning the
suitability of these products for individual investors, particularly those with longer holding
periods. To do this, we now need to model explicitly the evolution of security prices in
continuous time.
Specifically, the index level St is assumed to follow a geometric Brownian motion, as
given by:
dSt = µ St dt + σ St dWt (18)
with a drift rate of µ and a volatility of σ. Here, Wt in (18) is a Wiener process with a mean
of zero and a variance of t. Then ln(St ) follows a generalized Wiener process, as given by:
!
σ2
d ln(St ) = µ− dt + σ dWt (19)
2
We need to relate the dynamics of the NAV of a leveraged or inverse ETF to the dynamics
of the ETF’s underlying index level. From equation (7), it can be shown algebraically that:
Atn+1 − Atn Stn+1 − Stn
=x (20)
Atn Stn
Dynamics of Leveraged and Inverse ETFs 14
Since equation (20) holds for any period, when the time interval between tn and tn+1 is
sufficiently small, this expression becomes:
dAt dSt
=x (21)
At St
where At and St represent the NAV of a leveraged or inverse ETF and the ETF’s underlying
index level, respectively, at time t. Note that as described earlier, a leveraged ETF hedges
at discrete time intervals but always maintains economic exposure at x× the underlying
index return, as represented in equation (21).
With (21) and (18), it can be shown that:
suggesting that At follows a geometric Brownian motion with a drift rate of xµ and a
volatility of xσ. In other words, the volatility of a leveraged or inverse ETF is just x times
the volatility of its underlying index. This is handy for pricing options on leveraged and
inverse ETFs. Such options are gaining popularity and volume in parallel with activity in
their underlying ETFs, and there are now over 150 different option contracts traded on
these instruments.
where exp(z) = ez is the exponential function and z is a standard normal distribution with
a mean of zero and a standard deviation of one. So, the return to the index over the period,
2 √
ln(StN )−ln(S0 ), is normally distributed with mean [µ− σ2 ]tN and standard deviation σ tN .
Likewise, applying (23) to Atn and A0 will give us the following relationship of the leveraged
or inverse ETF’s NAV on day N and day 0:
" # !
x2 σ 2 √
AtN = A0 exp xµ − tN + xσ tN z (25)
2
In other words, the return to the leveraged ETF (ln(AtN ) − ln(A0 )) is normally distributed
2 2 √
with mean [xµ − x 2σ ]tN and standard deviation xσ tN . These draws are not independent,
however, because the same realization of the sample path, captured by z, is in both returns.
Dynamics of Leveraged and Inverse ETFs 15
Of course, the total return to a leveraged or inverse ETF along any sample path could
greatly exceed the underlying index return even if the holding period is relatively long. Note
the first term in equation (27) reflects the realized sample path of index returns. If the mean
return is large and positive and x > 0, then this term can imply substantial payoffs to the
leveraged ETF holder over many sample realizations. Consequently, it is of interest to
examine the expected value of a longer-term investment. This expression can be explicitly
derived using the moment generating function of the lognormal distribution. Specifically, if
Z is a random variable that is distributed normally with mean m and standard deviation
s, it can be shown that the expected value of exp (kZ) is
!
k 2 s2
E [exp (kZ)] = exp km + . (28)
2
2
Recall the N -period index gross return ln(StN ) − ln(S0 ) has a mean [µ − σ2 ]tN while the
2 2
corresponding x-times leveraged or inverse ETF has a mean [µx − x 2σ ]tN . Then, using
equation (28) with m equal to the corresponding mean, the expected gross return of the
2 2
index at time tN is exp([µ − σ2 ] tN + σ 2tN ) = exp(µ tN ), while the expected value of the
leveraged or inverse ETF is exp(x µ tN ). Intuitively, this result is a reflection of Jensen’s
inequality and the convexity of the exponential function. It follows immediately that if
xµ < 0 (i.e., an inverse ETF with positive index drift or a leveraged ETF with negative
index drift) that the expected value of a leveraged or inverse ETF will tend to zero, i.e., a
scenario of long-term value destruction.
It is important to understand that the expected value derived above is a mean value;
it is affected by the small probabilistic weight placed on extreme sample paths. Because
the lognormal distribution is positively skewed, the simple expectation is not likely the
typical experience of the average investor. Consider a simple numerical example: suppose
index returns are equally likely to be 4% or -2%. Over a successive two-day period, the
four possible cumulative returns are 8.16%, 1.92%, 1.92%, and -3.96%. The average two-
day cumulative return is thus 2.01%, but only one sample path (i.e., successive daily 4%
returns) of the four exceeds this figure. Since the skewness of the lognormal distribution
increases with variance, the mean value is especially unrepresentative for volatile assets.
Consequently, it makes sense to focus on the typical or median investor’s value change
over an interval of time. Again, from the properties of the lognormal distribution, if Z is
distributed normally with mean m and standard deviation s, the median value of exp (Z)
is exp (m), which does not depend on the variance.
2 2
Formally, substituting m = (xµ − x 2σ )tN for the mean return in a given interval of
time tN , we can now explicitly characterize situations in which leveraged or inverse ETFs
have a negative median return:
1. x < 0 (e.g., inverse and leveraged inverse ETFs) and µ > 0, i.e., the index drift is
positive;
x σ2
2. x > 0 (e.g., leveraged long ETFs) and 0 < µ < 2 ; and
In case 1, the returns to inverse ETF holders (i.e., x < 0) over long periods of time should
be negative because we expect µ > 0 in equilibrium so the first term in equation (27) will
also tend to zero as tN increases. In other words, the long-run inverse and leveraged inverse
ETF value is zero. In case 2, the variance term dominates µ so the leveraged ETF has a
negative drift. An interesting special case is where the index return has positive median
returns but the corresponding leveraged ETF is negative. Then, for x > 0, if µ satisfies:
σ2 2
2 < µ < xσ , the long-run return of the leveraged or inverse ETF is negative despite a
positive drift in the index. Case 3 – the polar opposite to case 1 – seems unlikely in a
long-run equilibrium, but is included for completeness.9
In summary, theory shows that leveraged and inverse ETFs are generally not suitable
for buy-and-hold investors.10 Indeed, it is possible for the median investor to face a nega-
tive return drift in a leveraged or inverse ETF although the underlying index has a positive
drift. But while levered products can yield less than x times the index return, their volatility
is exactly x times that of the index. From a long-run equilibrium perspective, the perfor-
mance drag is most problematic for inverse ETFs and products based on volatile underlying
indexes, as the return scalar also decreases with σ.
4.4 Frictions
From a practical standpoint, the cumulative impact of transaction costs can dramatically
affect the returns to a long-run investor in these ETFs. It is useful to distinguish between
explicit costs (e.g., management fees) and implicit costs (e.g., dealer hedging costs and the
impact costs arising from daily re-balancing activity) which represent a further drag on
longer-term performance.
Explicit costs are easy to account for as they are a constant fraction of the fund’s
AUM. Total expense ratios for leveraged and inverse ETFs range from 75-95 basis points,
which are high relative to traditional ETFs. But while explicit costs are transparent, the
hidden performance drag caused by implicit costs is not readily quantified and is not well
understood by investors.
Our previous discussion in Section 2.4 and examples provided in Tables 1, 2 and 3 did
not factor transaction cost. But as leveraged and inverse ETFs re-balance their exposure
of total return swaps on a daily basis, they will incur transaction costs and the cumulative
effect of the transaction costs on the ETFs’ performance cannot be under-estimated given
the daily nature of the funds’ re-balancing activity. In particular, these leveraged and
inverse ETFs should expect to pay fully or at least partially the bid-ask spread of adjusting
their total return swaps exposures. In addition, there may be market impact cost if the
re-balancing amount on a given day demands more liquidity than the market is able to
absorb in an orderly manner near the close. As mentioned in Section 3.1, the leveraged
and inverse ETFs are always buying when the underlying index is up, and selling when the
index is down. They will not only incur higher transaction cost because they almost always
9
In a general equilibrium framework, it is possible for a risky asset to have a long-run expected return
below the risk free rate if it acts as a hedge (e.g., with an embedded put), but this would seem unlikely for
an equity index.
10
See also Lu, Wang, and Zhang (2009) who reach a similar conclusion from an empirical analysis of longer
term leveraged ETF returns.
Dynamics of Leveraged and Inverse ETFs 19
demand liquidity when they re-balance daily, but also likely create a performance drag in
the long run.
We can model the impact of implicit transaction costs within the framework already
developed. Let us begin with the costs of establishing the swap position. These hedging
costs are visible to the fund (e.g., dealer spreads, etc.) but not to its investors. At the
beginning of each day, the fund pays a dealer a total transaction cost Ctn proportional
to the dollar amount of the total notional swap exposure. Let θ denote the hedging cost
(dealer’s fee) as a constant fraction of the notional amount of total return swaps required,
where 0 ≤ θ < 1, so that Ctn = θEtn . Net of costs, the exposure in equation (6) is just
scaled by (1 − θ), i.e., Etn+1 = (1 − θ)x Atn (1 + rtn , tn+1 ). Note that the risk free rate is
implicit in θ, although it is negligible at the daily level. The total notional swap exposure
is directly reduced by transaction costs (much like a tax) so that the gain or loss is (1 − θ)x
times the index’s performance between tn and tn+1 . So, equation (7) becomes
If we define x0 = (1 − θ)x, we see that the analysis of Section 4 goes through fully by
merely substituting x0 for x throughout. Since |x0 | < |x|, dealer transaction costs act as a
performance drag on the fund, reducing the promised returns.11
Daily fund re-balancing also imposes a further performance shortfall from what is
promised, as given by equation (2), due to market impact costs. We assume the market
impact cost is proportional to the size of the re-balancing trade each period. The expected
market impact cost, denoted by Mtn , is modeled as proportional to the absolute hedging
demand |∆tn |: h i
Mtn = E λ (x2 − x) |rtn−1 , tn | (30)
where λ > 0 is the market impact coefficient. Define by τ = tn − tn−1 the fixed re-
balancing interval, typically a day. From our previous results, the daily return rtn−1 , tn
√
is distributed normally with standard deviation σ τ . Assuming for convenience that the
daily mean return is negligible and using the results for the folded normal distribution (i.e.,
the distribution of the absolute value of a normal variate), the expected daily impact cost
is r
2 2τ
Mtn = λ (x − x)σ . (31)
π
This cost will be most evident over many days as the cumulative impact of these costs is
compounded and is manifested in the form of slippage from the benchmark index return.
From equation (31), we see that market impact costs increase with volatility, σ, the
market impact parameter, λ, the leverage factor, x, and the time between re-balances, τ .
We can use this analysis to understand the effects of changing the re-balancing frequency
(e.g., to twice a day or once a week) on the underlying economics. Interestingly, moving
to less frequent re-balancing can mitigate market impact costs. To see this, suppose we
increase the re-balancing interval to τ 0 = 2τ , i.e., every two trading days. Then, using
equation (31), the expected re-balancing impact cost for a two-day re-balancing interval is
44% higher than the daily expected cost, not double the daily value. Intuitively, impact costs
11
See, for example, Leland (1985) for an analysis of the impact of volatility on expected transaction costs
in the context of option pricing and replication.
Dynamics of Leveraged and Inverse ETFs 20
√
are proportional to the standard deviation of returns, which in turn increases with τ , the
square-root of the calendar re-balancing interval. So less frequent re-balancing implies less
absolute hedging and hence lower costs for a given calendar period. It is worth emphasizing
though that while a change in re-balancing frequency can affect implicit costs, it does not
alter the economics of the longer-run performance, as can be seen if tN is interpreted not
as days but as periods with µ and σ scaled appropriately.
Taxes represent another source of friction. Leveraged and inverse ETFs are not designed
with respect to tax efficiency and an investor’s after-tax performance might be significantly
lower than a strategy using leverage with less turnover. At year-end 2008, for example, the
major inverse ETF providers (Rydex and ProShares) paid out substantial capital gains tax
distributions ranging from 4% to 86%. The impact of taxes, however, will vary depending
on each individual investor’s particular circumstances.
are in effect designed to replicate a multiple of the underlying index’s return on a daily basis,
their exposures of total return swaps need to be re-balanced daily in order to produce the
leveraged returns promised. Whether the ETFs are leveraged, inverse or leveraged inverse,
their re-balancing activity is always in the same direction as the underlying index’s daily
performance: When the underlying index is up, the additional exposure of total return swaps
needs to be added; When the underlying index is down, the exposure of total return swaps
needs to be reduced. The cumulative effect of the transaction costs on the leveraged and
inverse ETFs’ performance cannot be underestimated given the daily nature of the funds’
re-balancing activity. The re-balance flows are executed as near the market close as possible
given their dependence on the close-to-close return of the underlying index. The need for
daily re-balancing is unique to the leveraged and inverse ETFs due to their product design.
Traditional ETFs that are not leveraged or inverse, whether they are holding physicals,
total return swaps or other derivatives, have no such need for daily re-hedging.
From a market structure perspective, many broker-dealers believe the end-of-day flows
needed to maintain the leverage promised by leveraged and inverse ETFs is having a height-
ened impact on liquidity and volatility of the underlying index and the securities comprising
the index at the close. Inverse ETFs in particular have a magnified hedging demand relative
to their long counterparts (e.g., as shown above, a 2× inverse ETF has the same hedging
multiplier as a 3× leveraged long ETF)13 The analysis above shows leveraged and inverse
ETFs amplify the market impact of all flows, irrespective of source. Essentially, these prod-
ucts require managers to “short gamma” by trading in the same direction as the market.
There is a close analogy to the role played by portfolio insurance in the crash of 1987.14
The magnitude of the potential impact is proportional to the amount of assets gathered
by these ETFs, the leveraged multiple promised, and the underlying index’s daily returns.
Such predictable and concentrated trading activity near the market closes may also create
an environment for front running and gaming.
These issues suggest regulators need to carefully consider the impact of point-in-time
liquidity demands when authorizing leveraged products, especially leveraged inverse prod-
ucts or products on relatively narrow, volatile indexes. Regulators, moreover, cannot easily
track the implicit exposure in a leveraged or inverse ETF (this is not the case if the un-
derlying ETF itself is levered), making it difficult to assess the market structure impact of
these products as their AUM changes over time. Developing a mechanism to track notional
exposure through total return swaps would alleviate some of the concerns arising from the
short gamma nature of the hedging strategy. Better disclosure might also help mitigate
broader counterparty credit risks. Fund companies are not required to disclose the details
of their swap agreements, making it difficult to determine counterparty credit quality. If
counterparties are unwilling or unable to provide total return swaps, the leveraged ETF
manager must replicate these returns using derivatives, which can be costly and induce
further tracking error.
Alternatives to existing products could be based on changing the re-balancing frequency.
However, shorter re-balancing (e.g., twice a day) will magnify intra-day price movements
13
These arguments could also extend to the Over-the-Counter (OTC) counterparts of leveraged ETFs and
to levered non-exchange traded funds.
14
See, e.g., Grossman and Vila (1989). The working paper underlying this article circulated prior to the
Crash of October 1987.
Dynamics of Leveraged and Inverse ETFs 23
while extending the re-balancing frequency (e.g., to weekly) increases the risk of the fund
being wiped out (i.e. as the fund becomes gradually similar to a statically hedged structure).
As long as product design is based on taking leveraged positions, the underlying economics
of these instruments is not altered.
Our results also raise questions of investor suitability. Some investors – despite very clear
language in the prospectuses – clearly do not understand the point that leveraged and inverse
ETFs will not necessarily replicate the leveraged index return over periods longer than a
day.15 Generally, the greater the holding period and the higher the daily volatility, the
greater the deviation between the leveraged ETF’s return and a statically levered position in
the same index. Note also that as leverage is embedded in the product, individual investors
can gain additional leverage by buying these products on margin. Better education, margin
restrictions, and tighter requirements on investor eligibility are possible options regulators
could consider. For example, some retail investors may be holding leveraged funds in
accounts that are not approved for margin, either because of lack of documentation or
in accounts (e.g., retirement) that explicitly exclude leverage.
Our analysis of return dynamics provides conditions under which buy-and-hold investors
experience eventual value destruction in leveraged or inverse ETFs, a point not well un-
derstood even by experts. The gross return of a leveraged or inverse ETF over a finite
time period can be shown algebraically to be simply the gross return of the ETF’s under-
lying index over the same period raised to the power of the leveraged multiple of the ETF,
multiplied by a scalar that is less than one. The NAV of a leveraged or inverse ETF is non-
negative (in contrast to the risk that a statically leveraged fund may see its NAV completely
wiped out) because a leveraged or inverse ETF dynamically adjusts its leveraged notional
amount of total return swaps on a daily basis depending on the performance of its under-
lying index. In effect, the leveraged and inverse ETFs have an embedded path-dependent
option on the underlying index. The value of the option is dependent on the entire path of
the underlying index. Specifically, if volatility is sufficiently high, the median investor will
experience a long-run erosion in value in a leveraged or inverse ETF.
Other considerations also might have a material impact on longer-term investors. Trans-
action costs in leveraged, inverse, and leveraged inverse ETFs may be higher than those
of replicating leveraged long or short exposure directly through swaps, options, futures, or
trading on margin. In addition, the cumulative impact of transaction costs arising from
daily re-balancing activity will only reduce these funds’ NAV further. There are also impor-
tant tax consequences, particularly with inverse ETFs. In essence, the leveraged and inverse
ETFs are not suitable for buy-and-hold investors. Neither are these products designed to
deliver long-term performance for volatile indexes.
15
See, e.g., Zweig (2009), who provides several examples of leveraged funds failing to track the underlying
index. Zweig notes, however, that: “Still, many financial advisors believe these funds are a good long-term
hedge against falling markets.”
Dynamics of Leveraged and Inverse ETFs 24
6 References
1. Despande, M., D. Mallick, and R. Bhatia (2009), “Understanding Ultrashort ETFs,”
Barclays Capital Special Report.
2. Dow Jones STOXX Index Guide (2009), “Dow Jones STOXX Index Guide,” STOXX
and Dow Jones, Inc.
4. Lauricella, T., S. Pulliam, and D. Gullapalli (2008), “Are ETFs Driving Late-Day
Turns? Leveraged Vehicles Seen Magnifying Other Bets; Last-Hour Volume Surge,”
Wall Street Journal, December 15, C1.
5. Leland, H. (1985), “Option Pricing and Replication with Transactions Costs,” Journal
of Finance, Vol. 40, No. 5, 1283-1301.
6. Lu, L., J. Wang, and G. Zhang (2009), “Long Term Performance of Leveraged ETFs”
Working paper, Baruch College.
7. Zweig, J. (2009), “How Managing Risk with ETFs Can Backfire,” Wall Street Journal,
February 28, B1.