Managerial Economics Lecture Notes
Managerial Economics Lecture Notes
Managerial Economics
B ECON 300
Market structure: market characteristics that determine the economic environment in which a firm operates. Characteristics: Number and size of firms (size refers to % of industry output supplied) Degree of product differentiation Barriers to entry (high vs. low/no barriers to entry)
Market power: a firm is said to have market power when it can raise the price of its output without losing all of its sales. Price taker: firm in the industry take the market price for their output as given: must charge the same market price as everyone else or demand will drop nearly to zero. The price-taking firm faces a perfectly elastic (horizontal) firm demand curve. Price setter: a price setting firm has some degree of market power, i.e., some ability of increasing price without losing all sales. The firm faces a downward sloping demand curve.
Perfect Competition
Monopolistic Competition
Oligopoly
Monopoly
Market Power
No market power
Large # of small firms supplying small % of output No product differentiation/ homogeneous Low barriers to entry
Large # of small firms supplying small % of output High degree of product differentiation Low barriers to entry
Product Differentiation
Barriers to Entry
Where: P (own price) price of the good for which we are estimating the demand M income PR price of related goods tastes PE expected future prices N number of consumers A linear form of the demand function is:
Note that the demand function is not necessarily linear, but it will be in most cases in this course and in all cases of this chapter. In the linear equation, b, c, d, e, f are called coefficients and/or slope parameters.
Complements in consumption: consume the goods together. Substitutes in consumption: consumers either consume on good or the other good
D1
Do
D0
D1
Q :
Where: P (Own price) price of the good for which we are estimating the supply PI price of inputs PR price of related goods technology PE expected future prices F number of firms
Complements in production: produce good X and good Y together (for example, as a result of the production, for instance steak and ground beef for a meat processing plant) Substitutes in production: either produce and sell good X or produce and sell good Y (for example, wheat and corn)
So
Q : Market equilibrium:
creates a surplus, as consumers would require a lower price to consume more. In order to determine the surplus, substitute the ceiling price in and in . determines the surplus.
D Q :
1 :
For instance, in the graph above, the consumer would pay up to P1 for the first unit. Supply price: the minimum price a supplier would require to supply for a particular unit of a product.
P : S
P1
1 :
Q :
For instance, in the graph above, the supplier would supply one unit if the price was P1. P CS
CS PE PS D
Q : In the graph above, PE is the market equilibrium price. The yellow triangle represents consumer surplus. In order to calculate the amount of consumer surplus, you need to find the area of the yellow triangle. Similarly, the blue triangle represents producer surplus and its area represents the amount of producer surplus created by this market.
Note that the demand tells you the direction that the variable will shift. Also, note that if both supply and demand move in the same direction, you can tell what happens to quantity. If they move in opposite directions, you can tell what happens to price.
Marginal Analysis
A common example comes from the theory of the firm. Firms want to maximize , where (Q) is the firms profit as a function of quantity. TR(Q) is total cost as a function of Q and TC(Q) is total cost as a function of Q. One experiment that can be run is the following: If the firm increases Q by a small amount, what happens to the profits? Do they increase, decrease or stay the same? Managers would want to keep increasing production as long as the profit increases and stop when the profit stops increasing. Mathematically, this means that to maximize profit, we will set the derivative of the profit function to zero.
Making
is to write
Where
Moreover:
Note that in the demand function the price coefficient needs to be negative. Therefore, the sign of is negative.
Another example of elasticity is the cross-price elasticity of demand. The cross-price elasticity of demand describes the sensitivity of the demand function to the change in the price of a related (complement or substitute) good.
The sign of the cross-price elasticity of demand is positive if the related good is a substitute and negative if the related good is a complement. Another one that is in the book is the elasticity of income: what happens to demand if income changes? Similarly:
The sign of the income elasticity of demand is positive for normal goods and negative for inferior goods. Lastly, we also have the advertising elasticity of demand.
Where A is the amount spent in advertising. The flatter the demand curve, the more quantity changes for a given price change.
Elasticity Rules
If | | | | |, we say that the demand is elastic. The quantity effect is larger than
,|
the price effect. One example is when there is a lot of substitutes. If | | ,| | | |, we say that the demand is inelastic. The quantity effect is smaller
than the price effect. If | | ,| | | |, we say that the demand is unit elastic.
Price Elasticity
Marginal Revenue
Elastic
|>1
Unit Elastic
|=1
MR = 0
Inelastic
|<1
1) Marginal revenue and inverse demand curve will have the same vertical axis intercept. 2) The slope of the marginal revenue is twice as steep as the inverse demand curve
Sales
Advertising In the figure above, blue dots are the observed values, the green line is the estimated equation once the estimation tool finds and and the red lines indicate the estimation errors. The estimation errors are squared to eliminate negative numbers.
Once and are found, the estimation tool also tell you the t-statistic of and . The t-statistic will give you a number that you could use to look on a t-statistic table and find a p-value, a number that tells you what is the probability that and could be zero instead of the value provided by the tool. Note that if was zero, there would be no relation between sales and advertising in the example. The p-values can be used to provide you with the level of confidence that the estimates of and are correct. Fortunately, most estimation tools will also provide the p-values, so you dont have to look on a table. You can choose the significance () that you are comfortable with. As a matter of tradition, in most sciences, p-values lower than =1% are considered to be strongly significant and pvalues lower than =5% are considered to be significant. In this course, we will use the Analysis Toolpak in Excel 2010 for Windows (which is provided through the technology funding). If you have a Mac, you can use a function called LINEST() or download StatPlus from the web. To enable the Analysis Toolpak, you have to configure the Excel Add-ins:
Mark the Analysis ToolPak and click Ok until you are back to Excel.
The Analysis ToolPak is going to be available under the Data tab on the Excel Ribbon. In order to access it, click on Data Analysis.
To run a regression with data, you need to have a theory that tells you what the function you are estimates look like (for example, Sales = a + b*Advertising, or Q = a + bP + cM). In Excel, the left-hand side of your equation is called Y and the right-hand side variables are called X. So if you have data for Advertising in cells B2 to B90 and data for Sales in A2 to A90, either select them with your mouse or type A2:A90 for Input Y Range and B2:B90 for Input X Range. Optionally, if your data includes a label (and you want to select it), make sure to include it with the values (therefore, A1:A90 for Sales and B1:B90 for Advertising) and check the Labels checkbox.
Look at the example below: A snapshot of the first few rows of the data:
The intercept (a) is estimated to be 90.63 and the slope (b) is estimated to be 2.15. So the best equation estimated by Excel is:
You can use the t-statistic (Ive painted them yellow) and find the p-value in a table, or look at the cells Ive painted blue. If you have more than one variable on the right hand side of the equation you want to estimate and you have data for it, just make sure to select it when choosing the Input X Values.
Where U is utility/happiness, X represents the quantity of good X consumed, Y represents the quantity of good Y consumed, M is the income/wealth, is the price per unity of good X, is the price per unity of good Y.
Assumptions:
1) Completeness: if the consumer prefers A to B and prefers B to A, they are indifferent between A and B. 2) Transitivity: if the consumer prefers A to B and B to C, then they prefer A to C. 3) Non-satiation: more is preferred to less (pig-principle). Indifference curve: level curve of the individuals utility function. Typical indifference curve will be negatively sloped and convex Different bundles along an indifference curve only differ in terms of how much X and Y is consumed. In the picture below, I and II are indifference curves. The consumer is indifferent between A and B and prefers C to both A and B. In an indifference curve, all bundles of goods along a given indifference curve have the same utility. Negative slope means that if order to gain some units of a good, the individual needs to give up some units of the other good.
Convexity: as the individual moves from bundle A to bundle B below, the individual is less and less willing to give up units of A in order to gain units of B.
Higher indifference curves have higher utility, so all points in curve II have more utility than any point in curve I.
Then the firms supply curve will be as follows. Note that the quantity produced at prices less than 30 will be zero and theres a discontinuity between Q = 0 and Q = 600.