Folly of A and B
Folly of A and B
Official goals are "purposely vague and general and do not indicate . . .
the host of decisions that must be made among alternative ways of achieving
official goals and the priority of multiple goals . . ." (8, p. 66). They
Steven Kerr (Ph.D.City University of New York) is Associate Professor of Organizational Behavior, College of Administrative Science, The Ohio State University, Columbus,
Ohio.
769
770
December
usually may be relied on to offend absolutely no one, and in this sense can be
considered high acceptance, low quality goals. An example might be
"build better schools." Operative goals are higher in quality but lower in
acceptance, since they specify where the money will come from, what
alternative goals will be ignored, etc.
The American citizenry supposedly wants its candidates for public office
to set forth operative goals, making their proposed programs "perfectly
clear," specifying sources and uses of funds, etc. However, since operative
goals are lower in acceptance, and since aspirants to public office need acceptance (from at least 50.1 percent of the people), most politicians prefer
to speak only of official goals, at least until after the election. They of course
would agree to speak at the operative level if "punished" for not doing so.
The electorate could do this by refusing to support candidates who do not
speak at the operative level.
Instead, however, the American voter typically punishes (withholds support from) candidates who frankly discuss where the money will come from,
rewards politicians who speak only of official goals, but hopes that candidates (despite the reward system) will discuss the issues operatively. It is
academic whether it was moral for Nixon, for example, to refuse to discuss
his 1968 "secret plan" to end the Vietnam war, his 1972 operative goals
concerning the lifting of price controls, the reshuffling of his cabinet, etc.
The point is that the reward system made such refusal rational.
It seems worth mentioning that no manuscript can adequately define
what is "moral" and what is not. However, examination of costs and benefits, combined with knowledge of what motivates a particular individual,
often will suffice to determine what for him is "rational."^ If the reward
system is so designed that it is irrational to be moral, this does not necessarily
mean that immortality will result. But is this not asking for trouble?
War
If some oversimplification may be permitted, let it be assumed that the
primary goal of the organization (Pentagon, Luftwaffe, or whatever) is to
win. Let it be assumed further that the primary goal of most individuals on
the front hnes is to get home alive. Then there appears to be an important
conffict in goalspersonally rational behavior by those at the bottom will
endanger goal attainment by those at the top.
But not necessarily! It depends on how the reward system is set up. The
Vietnam war was indeed a study of disobedience and rebellion, with terms
such as "fragging" (killing one's own commanding officer) and "search and
evade" becoming part of the military vocabulary. The difference in subordinates' acceptance of authority between World War II and Vietnam is
reported to be considerable, and veterans of the Second World War often
1 In Simon's (10, pp. 76-77) terms, a decision is "subjectively rational" if it maximizes an
individual's valued outcomes so far as his knowledge permits. A decision is "personally
rational" if it is oriented toward the individual's goals.
1975
771
have been quoted as being outraged at the mutinous actions of many Ameriican soldiers in Vietnam.
Consider, however, some critical differences in the reward system in use
during the two conflicts. What did the GI in World War II want? To go
home. And when did he get to go home? When the war was won! If he disobeyed the orders to clean out the trenches and take the hills, the war
would not be won and he would not go home. Furthermore, what were his
chances of attaining his goal (getting home alive) if he obeyed the orders
compared to his chances if he did not? What is being suggested is that the
rational soldier in World War II, whether patriotic or not, probably found it
expedient to obey.
Consider the reward system in use in Vietnam. What did the man at the
bottom want? To go home. And when did he get to go home? When his
tour of duty was over! This was the case whether or not the war was won.
Furthermore, concerning the relative chance of getting home alive by
obeying orders compared to the chance if they were disobeyed, it is worth
noting that a mutineer in Vietnam was far more likely to be assigned rest
and rehabilitation (on the assumption that fatigue was the cause) than he
was to suffer any negative consequence.
In his description of the "zone of indifference," Barnard stated that "a
person can and will accept a communication as authoritative only when . . .
at the time of his decision, he believes it to be compatible with his personal
interests as a whole" ( 1 , p. 165). In light of the reward system used in
Vietnam, would it not have been personally irrational for some orders to
have been obeyed? Was not the military implementing a system which
rewarded disobedience, while hoping that soldiers (despite the reward
system) would obey orders?
Medicine
Theoretically, a physician can make either of two types of error, and
intuitively one seems as bad as the other. A doctor can pronounce a patient
sick when he is actually well, thus causing him needless anxiety and expense, curtailment of enjoyable foods and activities, and even physical
danger by subjecting him to needless medication and surgery. Alternately, a
doctor can label a sick person well, and thus avoid treating what may be a
serious, even fatal ailment. It might be natural to conclude that physicians
seek to minimize both types of error.
Such a conclusion would be wrong.^ It is estimated that numerous Americans are presently afflicted with iatrogenic (physican caused) illnesses (9).
This occurs when the doctor is approached by someone complaining of a few
stray symptoms. The doctor classifies and organizes these symptoms, gives
them a name, and obligingly tells the patient what further symptoms may be
2 In one study (4) of 14,867 films for signs of tuberculosis, 1,216 positive readings turned
out to be clinically negative; only 24 negative readings proved clinically active, a ratio of 50
tol.
772
December
1975
773
If the reward system errs in the opposite direction, paying off only for
placements, extensive goal displacement again is likely to result. A common
example of vocational rehabilitation in many states, for example, consists of
placing someone in a job for which he has little interest and few qualifications, for two months or so, and then "rehabilitating" him again in another
position. Such behavior is quite consistent with the prevailing reward system,
which pays off for the number of individuals placed in any position for 60
days or more. Rehabilitation counselors also confess to competing with one
another to place relatively skilled clients, sometimes ignoring persons with
few skills who would be harder to place. Extensively disabled clients find
that counselors often prefer to work with those whose disabilities are less
severe.^
Universities
Society hopes that teachers will not neglect their teaching responsibilities
but rewards them almost entirely for research and publications. This is most
true at the large and prestigious universities. Cliches such as "good research
and good teaching go together" notwithstanding, professors often find that
they must choose between teaching and research oriented activities when
allocating their time. Rewards for good teaching usually are limited to outstanding teacher awards, which are given to only a small percentage of good
teachers and which usually bestow little money and fleeting prestige. Punishments for poor teaching also are rare.
Rewards for research and publications, on the other hand, and punishments for failure to accomplish these, are commonly administered by
universities at which teachers are employed. Furthermore, publication
oriented resumes usually will be well received at other universities, whereas
teaching credentials, harder to document and quantify, are much less transferable. Consequently it is i^ational for university teachers to concentrate
on research, even if to the detriment of teaching and at the expense of their
students.
By the same token, it is rational for students to act based upon the goal
displacement which has occurred within universities concerning what they
are rewarded for. If it is assumed that a primary goal of a university is to
transfer knowledge from teacher to student, then grades become identifiable
as a means toward that goal, serving as motivational, control, and feedback
devices to expedite the knowledge transfer. Instead, however, the grades
themselves have become much more important for entrance to graduate
school, successful employment, tuition refunds, parental respect, etc., than
the knowledge or lack of knowledge they are supposed to signify.
It therefore should come as no surprise that information has surfaced in
recent years concerning fraternity files for examinations, term paper writing
services, organized cheating at the service academies, and the like. Such
3 Personal interviews conducted during 1972-1973.
774
December
1975
775
December
776
Strongly encouraged employee participation in the survey, and made available time and space during the workday for completion of the instrument.
All employees in attendance during the day of the survey completed the
questionnaire. All instruments were collected directly by the researcher, who
personally administered each session. Since no one employed by the firm
handled the questionnaires, and since respondent names were not asked for,
it seems likely that the pledge of anonymity given was believed.
A modified version of the Expect Approval scale (7) was included as
part of the questiormaire. The instrument asked respondents to indicate the
degree of approval or disapproval they could expect if they performed each
of the described actions. A seven point Likert scale was used, with one
indicating that the action would probably bring strong disapproval and
seven signifying likely strong approval.
Although normative data for this scale from studies of other organizations
are unavailable, it is possible to examine fruitfully the data obtained from
this survey in several ways. First, it may be worth noting that the questionnaire data corresponded closely to information gathered through interviews. Furthermore, as can be seen from the results summarized in Table 1,
sizable differences between various work units, and between employees at
/different job levels within the same work unit, were obtained. This suggests
that response bias effects (social desirability in particular loomed as a potential concern) are not likely to be severe.
Most importantly, comparisons between scores obtained on the Expect
Approval scale and a statement of problems which were the reason for the
TABLE 1
Summary of Two Divisions' Data Relevant to
Conforming and Risk-Avoidance Behaviors
(Extent to Which Subjects Expect Approvai)
Percentage of Workers
Responding
Dimension
Risk
Avoidance
Item
Making a risky
decision based on
the best information available at
the time, but
which turns out
wrong.
1, 2, or 3
Division
Total
and Sample Responses Disapproval 4
5, 6, or 7
Approval
A, levels
1-4 (lowest)
127
61
25
14
A, levels
5-8
172
46
31
23
A, levels
9 and above
17
41
30
30
B, levels
1-4 (lowest)
31
58
26
16
B, levels
5-8
19
42
42
16
B, levels
9 and above
10
50
20
30
777
1975
TABLE 1 (Continued)
Percentage of Workers
Responding
Dimension
Risk
A voidance
(Continued)
Conformity
Item
Setting extremely
high and challenging standards and
goals, and then
narrowly failing
to make them.
1, 2, or 3
Division
Total
and Sample Responses Disapproval 4
5, 6, or 7
Approval
A, levels 1-4
122
47
28
25
A, levels 5-8
168
33
26
41
A, levels 9-1-
17
24
70
B, levels 1-4
31
48
23
29
B, levels 5-8
18
17
33
50
B, levels 9+
10
30
70
124
35
30
35
171
47
27
26
17
70
24
B, levels 1-4
31
58
26
16
B, levels 5-8
19
63
16
21
B, levels 9 +
10
80
20
A, levels 1-4
126
46
17
37
A, levels 5-8
180
54
14
31
A, levels 9 +
17
88
12
B, levels 1-4
32
53
28
19
B, levels 5-8
19
68
21
11
B, levels 9 +
10
80
10
10
Always going
along with the
majority.
Being careful to
stay on the good
side of everyone,
so that everyone
agrees that you
are a great guy.
A, levels 1-4
125
40
25
35
A, levels 5-8
173
47
21
32
A, levels 9-f
17
70
12
18
B, levels 1-4
31
61
23
16
B, levels 5-8
19
68
11
21
B, levels 9-|-
10
80
10
10
A, levels 1-4
124
45
18
37
A, levels 5-8
173
45
22
33
A, levels 94-
17
64
30
B, levels 1-4
31
54
23
23
B, levels 5-8
19
73
11
16
B, levels 9 +
10
80
10
10
778
December
survey revealed that the same behaviors which managers in each division
thought dysfunctional were those which lower level employees claimed were
rewarded. As compared to job levels 1 to 8 in Division B (see Table 1),
those in Division A claimed a much higher acceptance by management of
"conforming" activities. Between 31 and 37 percent of Division A employees at levels 1-8 stated that going along with the majority, agreeing
with the boss, and staying on everyone's good side brought approval; only
once (level 5-8 responses to one of the three items) did a majority suggest
that such actions would generate disapproval.
Furthermore, responses from Division A workers at levels 1-4 indicate
that behaviors geared toward risk avoidance were as likely to be rewarded as
to be punished. Only at job levels 9 and above was it apparent that the
reward system was positively reinforcing behaviors desired by top management. Overall, the same "tendencies toward conservatism and applepolishing at the lower levels" which divisional management had complained
about during the interviews were those claimed by subordinates to be the
most rational course of action in light of the existing reward system. Management apparently was not getting the behaviors it was hoping for, but it
certainly was getting the behaviors it was perceived by subordinates to be
rewarding.
An Insurance Firm
The Group Health Claims Division of a large eastern insurance company provides another rich illustration of a reward system which reinforces
behaviors not desired by top management.
Attempting to measure and reward accuracy in paying surgical claims,
the firm systematically keeps track of the number of returned checks and
letters of complaint received from policyholders. However, underpayments
are likely to provoke cries of outrage from the insured, while overpayments
often are accepted in courteous silence. Since it often is impossible to tell
from the physician's statement which of two surgical procedures, with different allowable benefits, was performed, and since writing for clarifications
will interfere with other standards used by the firm concerning "percentage
of claims paid within two days of receipt," the new hire in more than one
claims section is soon acquainted with the informal norm: "When in doubt,
pay it out!"
The situation would be even worse were it not for the fact that other
features of the firm's reward system tend to neutralize those described. For
example, annual "merit" increases are given to all employees, in one of the
following three amounts:
1. K the worker is "outstanding" (a select category, into which no more
than two employees per section may be placed): 5 percent
2. If the worker is "above average" (normally all workers not "outstanding" are so rated): 4 percent
1975
779
Nonetheless, many individuals seek to establish simple, quantifiable standards against which to measure and reward performance. Such efforts may
780
December
1975
781
CONCLUSIONS
Modern organization theory requires a recognition that the members of
organizations and society possess divergent goals and motives. It therefore is
unlikely that managers and their subordinates will seek the same outcomes.
Three possible remedies for this potential problem are suggested.
Selection
It is theoretically possible for organizations to employ only those individuals whose goals and motives are wholly consonant with those of management. In such cases the same behaviors judged by subordinates to be
rational would be perceived by management as desirable. State-of-the-art
reviews of selection techniques, however, provide scant grounds for hope
that such an approach would be successful (for example, see 12).
Training
Another theoretical alternative is for the organization to admit those
employees whose goals are not consonant with those of management and
then, through training, socialization, or whatever, alter employee goals to
make them consonant. However, research on the effectiveness of such training programs, though limited, provides further grounds for pessimism (for
example, see 3).
Altering the Reward System
What would have been the result if:
1. Nixon had been assured by his advisors that he could not win reelection except by discussing the issues in detail?
2. Physicians' conduct was subjected to regular examination by review
boards for type 1 errors (calling healthy people ill) and to penalties
(fines, censure, etc.) for errors of either type?
3. The President of XYZ Corporation had to choose between (a)
spending $11 million dollars for antipollution equipment, and (b)
incurring a fifty-fifty chance of going to jail for five years?
Managers who complain that their workers are not motivated might do
well to consider the possibility that they have installed reward systems which
are paying off for behaviors other than those they are seeking. This, in part,
is what happened in Vietnam, and this is what regularly frustrates societal
efforts to bring about honest politicians, civic-minded managers, etc. This
certainly is what happened in both the manufacturing and the insurance
companies.
A first step for such managers might be to find out what behaviors currently are being rewarded. Perhaps an instrument similar to that used in
the manufacturing firm could be useful for this purpose. Chances are
excellent that these managers will be surprised by what they findthat their
782
December
firms are not rewarding what they assume they are. In fact, such undesirable
behavior by organizational members as they have observed may be explained largely by the reward systems in use.
This is not to say that all organizational behavior is determined by formal
rewards and punishments. Certainly it is true that in the absence of formal
reinforcement some soldiers will be patriotic, some presidents will be
ecology minded, and some orphanage directors will care about children.
The point, however, is that in such cases the rewarder is not causing the
behaviors desired but is only a fortunate bystander. For an organization to
act upon its members, the formal reward system should positively reinforce desired behaviors, not constitute an obstacle to be overcome.
It might be wise to underscore the obvious fact that there is nothing
really new in what has been said. In both theory and practice these matters
have been mentioned before. Thus in many states Good Samaritan laws
have been installed to protect doctors who stop to assist a stricken motorist.
In states without such laws it is commonplace for doctors to refuse to stop,
for fear of involvement in a subsequent lawsuit. In college basketball
additional penalties have been instituted against players who foul their opponents deliberately. It has long been argued by Milton Friedman and others
that penalties should be altered so as to make it irrational to disobey the
ecology laws, and so on.
By altering the reward system the organization escapes the necessity of
selecting only desirable people or of trying to alter undesirable ones. In
Skinnerian terms (as described in 11, p. 704), "As for responsibility and
goodnessas commonly definedno one . . . would want or need them.
They refer to a man's behaving well despite the absence of positive reinforcement that is obviously sufficient to explain it. Where such reinforcement
exists, 'no one needs goodness.' "
REFERENCES
1. Barnard, Chester I. The Functions of the Executive (Cambridge, Mass.: Harvard University Press, 1964).
2. Blau, Peter M., and W. Richard Scott. Formal Organizations (San Francisco: Chandler,
1962).
3. Fiedler, Fred E. "Predicting the Eflfects of Leadership Training and Experience from
the Contingency Model," Journal of Applied Psychology, Vol. 56 (1972), 114-119.
4. Garland, L. H. "Studies of the Accuracy of Diagnostic Procedures," American Journal
Roentgenological, Radium Therapy Nuclear Medicine, Vol. 82 (1959), 25-38.
5. Kerr, Steven. "Some Modifications in MBO as an OD Strategy," Academy of Management Proceedings, 1973, pp. 39-42.
6. Kerr, Steven. "What Price Objectivity?" American Sociologist, Vol. 8 (1973), 92-93.
7. Litwin, G. H., and R. A. Stringer, Jr. Motivation and Organizational Climate (Boston:
Harvard University Press, 1968).
8. Perrow, Charles. "The Analysis of Goals in Complex Organizations," in A. Etzioni (Ed.),
Readings on Modern Organizations (Englewood Cliffs, N. J.: Prentice-Hall, 1969).
9. Scheff, Thomas J. "Decision Rules, Types of Error, and Their Consequences in Medical
Diagnosis," in F. Massarik and P. Ratoosh (Eds.), Mathematical Explorations in Behavioral Science (Homewood, 111.: Irwin, 1965).
10. Simon, Herbert A. Administrative Behavior (New York: Free Press, 1957).
1975
783