Collective Resistance in China: Why Popular Protests Succeed or Fail
By Yongshun Cai
5/5
()
About this ebook
Although academics have paid much attention to contentious politics in China and elsewhere, research on the outcomes of social protests, both direct and indirect, in non-democracies is still limited. In this new work, Yongshun Cai combines original fieldwork with secondary sources to examine how social protest has become a viable method of resistance in China and, more importantly, why some collective actions succeed while others fail.
Cai looks at the collective resistance of a range of social groups—peasants to workers to homeowners—and explores the outcomes of social protests in China by adopting an analytical framework that operationalizes the forcefulness of protestor action and the cost-benefit calculations of the government. He shows that a protesting group's ability to create and exploit the divide within the state, mobilize participants, or gain extra support directly affects the outcome of its collective action. Moreover, by exploring the government's response to social protests, the book addresses the resilience of the Chinese political system and its implications for social and political developments in China.
Related to Collective Resistance in China
Related ebooks
The Life and Journeys of a Dabizi: (Big Nosed Foreigner) in China – from Mao to Hu Rating: 0 out of 5 stars0 ratingsFollowing the Leader: Ruling China, from Deng Xiaoping to Xi Jinping Rating: 4 out of 5 stars4/5Accepting Authoritarianism: State-Society Relations in China's Reform Era Rating: 4 out of 5 stars4/5The Government Next Door: Neighborhood Politics in Urban China Rating: 0 out of 5 stars0 ratingsPranksters vs. Autocrats: Why Dilemma Actions Advance Nonviolent Activism Rating: 3 out of 5 stars3/5Government and the Society It Serves: The Difference Between Waiting for Political Decisions and Making Them Rating: 0 out of 5 stars0 ratingsHow to Win Well: Civil Resistance Breakthroughs and the Path to Democracy Rating: 0 out of 5 stars0 ratingsWhen Civil Resistance Succeeds: Building Democracy After Nonviolent Uprisings Rating: 0 out of 5 stars0 ratingsRoots of the State: Neighborhood Organization and Social Networks in Beijing and Taipei Rating: 0 out of 5 stars0 ratingsCivil Disobedience: A Practical Guide Rating: 1 out of 5 stars1/5The Politics of Compassion: The Sichuan Earthquake and Civic Engagement in China Rating: 0 out of 5 stars0 ratingsMaking of an African Giant: State, Politics and Public Policy in Nigeria, Vol. One Rating: 0 out of 5 stars0 ratingsGale Researcher Guide for: Community Governance Rating: 0 out of 5 stars0 ratingsStatecraft and Society in China: Grassroots politics in China Rating: 0 out of 5 stars0 ratingsChina's Water Warriors: Citizen Action and Policy Change Rating: 0 out of 5 stars0 ratingsSite Fights: Divisive Facilities and Civil Society in Japan and the West Rating: 0 out of 5 stars0 ratingsTake Back Our Future: An Eventful Sociology of the Hong Kong Umbrella Movement Rating: 0 out of 5 stars0 ratingsUseful Bullshit: Constitutions in Chinese Politics and Society Rating: 0 out of 5 stars0 ratingsClass Work: Vocational Schools and China's Urban Youth Rating: 0 out of 5 stars0 ratingsIrregular Warfare: Tactics and Strategies for Modern Conflict Rating: 0 out of 5 stars0 ratingsSocial Forces and States: Poverty and Distributional Outcomes in South Korea, Chile, and Mexico Rating: 0 out of 5 stars0 ratingsA COVID Charter, A Better World Rating: 0 out of 5 stars0 ratingsShanghai Gone: Domicide and Defiance in a Chinese Megacity Rating: 0 out of 5 stars0 ratingsNew China: Reflections, Analysis and Conclusions of a Layman Rating: 0 out of 5 stars0 ratingsThe Checklist to End Tyranny: How Dissidents Will Win 21st Century Civil Resistance Campaigns Rating: 0 out of 5 stars0 ratingsInsurgency Trap: Labor Politics in Postsocialist China Rating: 0 out of 5 stars0 ratingsThe politics of attack: Communiqués and insurrectionary violence Rating: 0 out of 5 stars0 ratingsFostering a Fourth Democratic Wave Rating: 0 out of 5 stars0 ratingsCapitalism without Democracy: The Private Sector in Contemporary China Rating: 4 out of 5 stars4/5
Politics For You
The Cult of Trump: A Leading Cult Expert Explains How the President Uses Mind Control Rating: 3 out of 5 stars3/5The Parasitic Mind: How Infectious Ideas Are Killing Common Sense Rating: 4 out of 5 stars4/5The Republic by Plato Rating: 4 out of 5 stars4/5The Real Anthony Fauci: Bill Gates, Big Pharma, and the Global War on Democracy and Public Health Rating: 4 out of 5 stars4/5Daily Stoic: A Daily Journal On Meditation, Stoicism, Wisdom and Philosophy to Improve Your Life Rating: 5 out of 5 stars5/5Capitalism and Freedom Rating: 4 out of 5 stars4/5Fear: Trump in the White House Rating: 4 out of 5 stars4/5Unhumans: The Secret History of Communist Revolutions (and How to Crush Them) Rating: 3 out of 5 stars3/5Government Gangsters: The Deep State, the Truth, and the Battle for Our Democracy Rating: 4 out of 5 stars4/5How to Hide an Empire: A History of the Greater United States Rating: 4 out of 5 stars4/5The U.S. Constitution with The Declaration of Independence and The Articles of Confederation Rating: 4 out of 5 stars4/5Closing of the American Mind Rating: 4 out of 5 stars4/5Twilight of the Shadow Government: How Transparency Will Kill the Deep State Rating: 0 out of 5 stars0 ratingsFreedom Is a Constant Struggle: Ferguson, Palestine, and the Foundations of a Movement Rating: 4 out of 5 stars4/5The Madness of Crowds: Gender, Race and Identity Rating: 4 out of 5 stars4/5Dark Money: how a secretive group of billionaires is trying to buy political control in the US Rating: 5 out of 5 stars5/5The Wretched of the Earth Rating: 4 out of 5 stars4/5Jordan Peterson: Critical Responses Rating: 4 out of 5 stars4/5How to Become Anonymous, Secure and Free Online Rating: 5 out of 5 stars5/5This Is How They Tell Me the World Ends: The Cyberweapons Arms Race Rating: 4 out of 5 stars4/5The Sovereign Individual: Mastering the Transition to the Information Age Rating: 4 out of 5 stars4/5Follow the Money: The Shocking Deep State Connections of the Anti-Trump Cabal Rating: 4 out of 5 stars4/5While Time Remains: A North Korean Defector's Search for Freedom in America Rating: 4 out of 5 stars4/5
Reviews for Collective Resistance in China
1 rating0 reviews
Book preview
Collective Resistance in China - Yongshun Cai
THE WALTER H. SHORENSTEIN ASIA-PACIFIC RESEARCH CENTER
Studies of the Walter H. Shorenstein Asia-Pacific Research Center
Andrew G. Walder, General Editor
The Walter H. Shorenstein Asia-Pacific Research Center in the Freeman Spogli Institute for International Studies at Stanford University sponsors interdisciplinary research on the politics, economies, and societies of contemporary Asia. This monograph series features academic and policy-oriented research by Stanford faculty and other scholars associated with the Center.
ALSO PUBLISHED IN THE SHORENSTEIN ASIA-PACIFIC RESEARCH CENTER SERIES
One Alliance: Two Lenses: U.S.-Korea Relations in a New Era
Gi-Wook Shin (2010)
The Chinese Cultural Revolution as History
Edited by Joseph W. Esherick, Paul G. Pickowicz, and Andrew G. Walder (2006)
Ethnic Nationalism in Korea: Genealogy, Politics, and Legacy
Gi-Wook Shin (2006)
Prospects for Peace in South Asia
Edited by Rafiq Dossani and Henry S. Rowen (2005)
Collective Resistance in China
Why Popular Protests Succeed or Fail
Yongshun Cai
Stanford University Press
Stanford, California
© 2010 by the Board of Trustees of the Leland Stanford Junior University.
All rights reserved.
No part of this book may be reproduced or transmitted in any form or by any means, electronic or mechanical, including photocopying and recording, or in any information storage or retrieval system without the prior written permission of Stanford University Press.
Printed in the United States of America on acid-free, archival-quality paper
Library of Congress Cataloging-in-Publication Data
Cai, Yongshun.
Collective resistance in China : why popular protests succeed or fail / Yongshun Cai.
p. cm.—(Studies of the Walter H. Shorenstein Asia-Pacific Research Center) Includes bibliographical references and index.
9780804773737
ISBN 978-0-8047-6340-0 (pbk. : alk. paper)
1. Social movements—China. 2. Protest movements—China. 3. Political
participation—China. 4. China—Politics and government—1976–2002.
5. China—Politics and government—2002–I. Title. II. Series: Studies of the
Walter H. Shorenstein Asia-Pacific Research Center.
HN733.5.C365 2010
303.60951’09045—dc22
2009019445
Typeset by Thompson Type in 11/14 Adobe Garamond
For Wang Chen and Xinyu
Table of Contents
THE WALTER H. SHORENSTEIN ASIA-PACIFIC RESEARCH CENTER
ALSO PUBLISHED IN THE SHORENSTEIN ASIA-PACIFIC RESEARCH CENTER SERIES
Title Page
Copyright Page
Dedication
Table of Figures
List of Tables
Acknowledgments
ONE - Introduction
TWO - Social Conflicts and Collective Resistance in China
THREE - Obstacles to Successful Resistance in China
FOUR - Issue Linkage and Effective Resistance
FIVE - Social Networks and Effective Resistance
SIX - The Power of Disruptive Collective Action
SEVEN - The Limits of Disruptive Tactics: The Use of Violence
EIGHT - Popular Resistance and Policy Adjustment
NINE - Conclusion
APPENDIXES - Data Collection
Notes
Bibliography
Index
Table of Figures
FIGURE 2.1
FIGURE 3.1
FIGURE 4.1
FIGURE 6.1
FIGURE 8.1
FIGURE 8.2
FIGURE D.1
FIGURE E.1
FIGURE F.1
List of Tables
TABLE 1.1
TABLE 2.1
TABLE 2.2
TABLE 2.3
TABLE 3.1
TABLE 3.2
TABLE 3.3
TABLE 3.4
TABLE 3.5
TABLE 4.1
TABLE 6.1
TABLE 6.2
TABLE 6.3
TABLE 7.1
TABLE 7.2
TABLE 8.1
TABLE 8.2
TABLE 8.3
TABLE 8.4
TABLE 8.5
TABLE 8.6
TABLE 8.7
TABLE 8.8
TABLE A.1
TABLE B.1
TABLE C.1
TABLE D.1
TABLE E.1
TABLE F.1
Acknowledgments
I received help from many people during the process of writing this book. Over the years, Jean Oi has never hesitated to give me intellectual support and encouragement, and she has continued to be a patient reader of my manuscripts and to offer comments and suggestions. I would also like to thank Andrew Walder for his suggestions on the manuscript and for his encouragement. Ever since I became interested in contentious politics in China, I have benefited from, among many others, the works by Kevin O’Brien and Lianjiang Li and from my communications with them. When the book manuscript was under review at the Stanford University Press, Kevin O’Brien was one of the two anonymous reviewers. His comments and suggestions helped me to place the case of China in a broader theoretical context. I also wish to thank the other anonymous reviewer whose insightful suggestions helped me to clarify issues about my framework as well as the process of interactions among the different parties involved in collective resistance in China.
I would like to thank Shi Fayong, Guo Jiguang, and Li Siliang for their assistance in collecting the data for this book. I also wish to thank Virginia Unkefer and Margaret Pinette for their editorial assistance. Research for this book was partly financed by the Research Grants Council of Hong Kong (640108) and the Chiang Ching-kuo Foundation (RG008-P-07).
At Stanford University Press, I wish to thank Stacy Wagner and Jessica Walsh for their patience and their support for the book.
Part of Chapter Five originally appeared in Disaggregating the State: Networks and Collective Resistance in Shanghai
(by Fayong Shi and Yongshun Cai), The China Quarterly (published by Cambridge University Press), volume 186: pp. 314–332 (2006). I wish to thank Cambridge University Press and Fayong Shi for allowing me to include this article in Chapter Five.
Finally, I would like to thank my family for their support for my research over the years. My wife, Wang Chen, has been the source of support and encouragement ever since I began my academic life. I also wish to thank my daughter, Xinyu, for the joyful moments she has given me. Although she believed that I should write interesting books for kids, she tolerated my spending much time on the research for this project. This book is dedicated to them.
ONE
Introduction
Popular resistance has become an important mode of political participation in China since the early 1990s. Various groups of people, including workers, peasants, and homeowners, have resorted to this mode of action to protect or pursue their interests.¹ Numerous contentious incidents have put serious pressure on the party-state. It is against this background that building a so-called harmonious society has recently become a top priority of the central party-state.² The collective acts of resistance have occurred not only because there have been widespread violations of citizens’ rights but also because this mode of action helps citizens to defend or pursue their legitimate rights. As elsewhere, people stage collective resistance not simply because they want to send a signal of impatience or frustration but also because they have some reason to think it will help their cause.
³ In China, some protestors have been successful in their resistance,⁴ and, more importantly, their resistance has also led or contributed to changes in some unfavorable policies.
On the other hand, popular contention is by no means an easy or safe undertaking in China. In recent years, many participants in non-regime-threatening collective resistance have been detained, arrested, or imprisoned. ⁵ For example, in a county in the Guangxi Autonomous Region, peasants from a village resisted a 2004 court ruling regarding ownership of a piece of land. In January 2005, the local government arrested twenty-seven peasant activists. When more than 200 villagers approached the local authorities demanding the release of the activists, they were accused of attacking state agencies, and about 110 were detained. Seventeen villagers were sentenced to jail terms of up to eight years, ten were sent to labor camps for up to two years, and another eighty-two were released on bail after paying between 2,000 and 8,000 yuan.⁶ The limitations to popular resistance also lie in the fact that the government may refuse to adjust policies that disadvantage certain groups despite their grievances and resistance.
That authoritarian governments should use suppression to deal with disobedient citizens is not surprising: In democracies, politicians face the pressure of (re)election and therefore have to be cautious when using repressive tactics. They are, thus, more tolerant of nonviolent dissident behavior and may use a mix of concessions and repression to suppress such actions when necessary. In contrast, political leaders in authoritarian regimes, who are less concerned with election, rely more on repression to demonstrate the state’s power and determination to protect the political system.⁷ In the communist regimes of Eastern Europe, for example, legalized repression
was used to silence citizens.⁸ By and large, popular resentment, though profound, did not manifest itself openly,
Kecskemeti explains, as protesting in public was not only prohibitively risky but also futile, since no potential alternative to the prevailing system was visible.
⁹
This mixed picture of the outcome of popular resistance in China raises two important questions. Why do some instances of resistance succeed while others fail in this nondemocratic regime? When is popular resistance more likely to contribute to policy changes? This study aims to answer these questions and promote an understanding of the operation of the Chinese political system and of contentious politics in a nondemocratic setting. To explain why some actions succeed while others fail, we need to examine the mechanisms through which people staging resistance exercise influence or the factors that affect the outcomes of their actions. This study shows that both the government, which is responsible for dealing with popular resistance, and the resisters face constraints in their interactions with each other. The resisters’ chance of success lies in their ability to exploit the constraints facing the government or to (re)shape the latter’s cost-benefit calculations in a way that suppressing or ignoring an act of resistance is not a feasible or desirable option.
Protest Outcomes in China
As the ultimate end of collective action such as social movements is to bring about change, recent research on collective action has paid increasing attention to outcomes.¹⁰ Gamson suggests that the outcomes of social movements or protests fall into two basic clusters, one concerned with the fate of the challenging group as an organization and one with the distribution of new advantages to the group’s beneficiary.
¹¹ Subsequent research has expanded on Gamson’s work.¹² The current consensus is that the outcomes of collective action may take different forms, including political, economic, social, and cultural changes.¹³ Consequently, the outcomes of social protests can be divided into three categories: (1) the outcome of individual incidents of collective action; (2) the aggregate impact of collective action staged by members of a social group; and (3) the enduring or indirect effect of social protests. This book explores the factors that affect these three types of outcomes of popular contention in China.
Research on social movements or protests has pointed to the different factors that affect the effectiveness and outcomes. One is the political opportunity structure that determines whether social movements can rise or develop in the first place.¹⁴ A second group of factors is the power of a protesting group, which has to do with the protesting group’s solidarity, organizational bases, and resources.¹⁵ Collective action tactics are also found to influence the effectiveness of protests, especially among politically weak groups.¹⁶ Finally, the chance of success has much to do with the protesters’ demands, which determine the cost of making concessions on the part of the actor being targeted. For example, groups that intend to displace those in power or make broad changes in the political system are unlikely to succeed.¹⁷
All these findings shed important light on the outcomes of social protests in China by pointing to some of the basic conditions for successful action. But many of these findings are based on research on social movements in democracies. One factor that makes the handling of social protests in China different from that of many social movements in democracies is the role of the government. Social movements in democracies may not directly target the government or may not have a specific target at all. Governments in democracies are thus less sensitive to such actions if they do not seriously violate the law. Indeed, citizens in these regimes can even get permission for holding demonstrations. In contrast, governments in authoritarian regimes are much more sensitive to popular resistance. The occurrence of such incidents may signal problems with social control or the weakness of the government because such events are not supposed to occur in a regime where citizens are denied the right to disrupt the system.¹⁸
Authoritarian governments’ high sensitivity to popular resistance implies that they are more committed to the settlement of collective action than are their counterparts in democracies. In research on the settlement of protests in democracies, the strategies used by the police are an important focus.¹⁹ In research on protests in China, more attention needs to be paid to the interactions between the governments and the protesters. This does not mean that the police in China do not play an important role in dealing with collective action.²⁰ However, the decision on how to handle collective incidents, especially large ones, is generally made by the government. For example, a survey of more than 1,000 police officers in Fujian province in 2005 showed that 80 percent reported that the ultimate decision on the settlement of collective incidents was made by the party committee and/ or the government or their top leaders and not by the police.²¹ Therefore, protest outcomes in China are often directly affected or determined by the response of the government at the local or central level.
The Rationale behind Government Response in China
Research on the government’s reaction to collective action in democracies reveals the following modes of response: tolerance, repression, concessions, or a combination of concessions and repression.²² However, this research has generally focused on one level of the government (e.g., the national level). In China, local governments rather than the central government have most frequently been targeted by protesters. This is the case because, first, local authorities may directly violate citizens’ rights, distort the central government’s policies, or fail to protect citizens’ rights.²³ County, township, or city governments or their agencies are much more frequently sued by citizens than is the provincial or central government.²⁴ Second, the concentration of power implies the concentration of responsibility. Local authorities are targeted because they are responsible for daily governance and are believed to have the power and responsibility to address citizens’ grievances.²⁵ Given the power of the local government, when competing groups fight against each other (businesses versus citizens, for example),²⁶ the outcome is largely determined by the government, which has decisive influence over the legal system and commerce at each level.
On the other hand, local governments in China are embedded in the political hierarchy topped by the central government. This political system grants local governments conditional autonomy: They have considerable autonomy in dealing with popular resistance while facing constraints imposed by the central government. Therefore, the chance of success depends not only on the particular local governments that are targeted by protestors but also on the interaction between different levels of state authorities.
Many studies on popular resistance in China have shown that a favorable environment for protest in the Chinese context does not necessarily result from significant changes in the political system that create political opportunities.²⁷ Instead, opportunities for resistance in China normally arise from the divide between state authorities at different levels (i.e., the central versus the local). Given the political hierarchy, it has been commonly accepted that intervention from the central government or upper-level local governments is a crucial way of achieving successful resistance in China.²⁸ But what has been inadequately explored is under what circumstances such intervention is possible. In other words, why have some instances been subject to intervention while many others have not? Under what circumstances is successful resistance possible in the absence of intervention from above? Why has the government changed certain policies but not others, although both kinds of policy have caused grievances and resistance? Answering these questions requires a systematic examination of the constraints and power of the governments at different levels, in particular the costs of concessions incurred by the government in dealing with popular contention.
This book suggests that the governments at different levels may have different perceptions of costs and benefits in addressing citizens’ resistance and that their perceptions shape their choice of the mode of response, thereby determining not only the opportunity for resistance but also the outcome. For analytical convenience, I divide the state authorities in China into the central government and local governments. Both levels of government may adopt one of the following modes of response to deal with popular resistance: (1) concessions (i.e., citizens’ demands are met); (2) concessions with discipline (i.e., citizens’ demands are met, but some or all participants are punished); (3) tolerance (i.e., citizens’ demands are ignored, but the government also tolerates their resistance); and (4) repression (i.e., citizens’ demands are ignored, and some or all participants are punished).
A crucial factor that makes the central government behave differently than local governments is its greater interest in protecting the regime’s legitimacy. ²⁹ Legitimacy is about the political system’s worthiness to be recognized. ³⁰ Given that the central government is more responsible for the operation of the political system or it largely represents the regime, it has a greater interest in protecting the regime’s legitimacy. In contrast, local officials in China are more concerned with policy implementation or task fulfillment (e.g., maintaining social stability) and local issues; thus, legitimacy is not their main concern.³¹ A simple comparison of the incentive structures faced by the two levels of government reveals that the central government’s more serious concern about legitimacy helps to make it more tolerant than local governments of non-regime-threatening popular resistance.
The central and local governments incur two types of costs when concessions are made: (1) economic and/or political costs; and (2) signs of weakness (Table 1.1). Addressing citizens’ complaints may require the expenditure of financial resources (economic costs). It may also require the government to correct its practices or policies or discipline state agents deemed responsible for the grievances or resistance (political costs). The cost of showing weakness is that making concessions may trigger more demands or actions. If the cost of showing weakness is considered to be the same for the two levels of government, then the central government incurs a smaller cost than the local government does when making concessions. First, when the central government intervenes in a dispute and makes concessions, it often requires the local government to address citizens’ grievances with local financial resources. Thus, the local government has to shoulder the cost. Second, when malfeasant or irresponsible local officials are disciplined, the local government incurs a heavier loss because it relies more directly on these officials for local governance than the central government does. As far as the benefits are concerned, if stopping resistance is equally desirable to the two levels of government, the central government gains more because legitimacy is more important to the central government than to the local government.
In the case of repression, the two levels of government also incur two types of costs: (1) loss of legitimacy and (2) risk from repression (Table 1.1). Repressing citizens’ resistance with legitimate claims damages the regime’s legitimacy. For the reasons discussed above, the central government faces a higher cost from losing legitimacy than does the local government when repression is used.
The other type of cost incurred from repression is the risk arising from ineffective or failed repressive measures. For the central government, the risk is that ineffective repression leads to more serious or regime-threatening resistance. This possibility (or the risk) is rather small given the power of the central party-state in China. In contrast, the local government faces a more serious risk in repressing resistance. For one, ineffective repression may cause the escalation of resistance, which signals the local government’s failure in maintaining social stability. For another, forceful repression that results in serious casualties will damage regime legitimacy.³² In either situation, the central government will intervene, and local officials may be punished. However, the local government will face a small cost from repression if it is able to use the modes of repression that carry little risk (given that legitimacy is not its main concern). Hence, when the risk from repression is low for both levels of government, the local government is more likely to use repression than is the central government.
TABLE 1.1
Costs and Benefits in Concessions and Repression
SOURCE: Author’s summary.
Nonetheless, although the central government is more tolerant of citizens’ resistance, its concessions are conditional. When the central government decides to make concessions to citizens, it often means that it will intervene in the conflict between citizens and the local government. This is likely when the central government feels pressure to stop the resistance and protect regime legitimacy. Conversely, the central government is very unlikely to intervene in disputes that are peaceful and small in scale simply because the pressure for intervention is small.
These conditions for the central government’s intervention affect the local governments’ responses. Local governments will use concessions or concessions with discipline to stop citizens’ resistance quickly when facing intervention or a threat of intervention from the central government. However, in the absence of intervention or when the likelihood of intervention is negligibly small, local governments assume considerable autonomy in choosing the mode of response. Concessions will be difficult if (1) the local government faces high economic or political costs; and (2) partial concessions or tolerance results in persistent resistance that threatens social stability or the images of local leaders. In these circumstances, repression is a low-cost option.
The incentive structure faced by the two levels of government in China is crucial to our understanding of the outcomes of collective resistance. From the perspective of protesters or resisters, their chance of success, either in individual instances of resistance or in the case of policy change, is jointly determined by the type of demand, which determines the costs of concessions incurred by the government, and the forcefulness of their resistance. Their ability to achieve successful resistance thus depends on whether they can effectively exploit the constraints faced by the two levels of government. In this book, I define the success or failure of citizen resistance in light of the goals claimed by the participants. An instance is seen as successful if the participants achieve their goal entirely or partly.
Seeking Success
It is not new to apply the cost-benefit approach to analyzing government responses to popular contention.³³ What needs to be stressed is that neither the cost nor the benefits to the government should be treated as fixed or predetermined. The government’s perception of the cost and benefits is weighed against the power of the resisters or the forcefulness of their action. In China, although the citizens are generally weak in relation to the government, the nonmonolithic nature of the party-state implies that there does exist the political space for successful resistance. Therefore, the outcome of popular resistance should be viewed as the result of a dynamic interaction between the government and the protestors. This is crucial to understanding the resisters’ chance of success because it points to the importance of strategies, resources, and other factors that affect the power of the participants. The dynamic interaction can also be understood as a process of creating or expanding opportunities for resistance. Political opportunities are found to affect the efficacy of social movements,³⁴ but the opportunities may not be predetermined. They can be created when protestors resort to certain modes of action or strategies.³⁵
In China, citizens’ resistance is mostly directed at local governments; or at least it starts by targeting local governments. The incentive structure discussed above suggests that it is inaccurate to assume that local governments in China are always reluctant to make concessions if the cost of doing so is small. The difficulty of making concessions lies in those cases with high-cost demands. However, because the most serious constraint on local officials is that imposed by upper-level authorities, the citizens can stage successful action if they are able to make the local government eager to stop popular contention while preventing it from relying on suppression. A fundamental way of achieving this goal is to seek or threaten to seek favorable intervention from higher authorities. This is possible when participants are able to gain extra leverage over local officials, generate support from within the state, or stage powerful disruptive action to strengthen their intervention-seeking ability.
GAINING EXTRA LEVERAGE
In China, a protesting group can seek intervention from upper-level authorities, including the central government, through permitted channels (e.g., petitions) or noninstitutionalized action, such as protests. In using permitted channels, a groups’ intervention-seeking ability is affected by the timing of its action in the sense that, if an issue is high on the agenda of the central or provincial government, the window of opportunity is more accessible. But not all citizens’ issues are high on the agenda of the central or provincial government. Moreover, citizen resistance may still be ignored even if an issue is of high importance. For example, when citizen complaints are numerous, the threshold for central or provincial government intervention is inevitably raised. Therefore, an important factor that affects a group’s ability to seek intervention is whether it can find extra leverage over malfeasant or irresponsive local officials.
Resisters’ extra leverage means extra constraints on local officials, which may make the local officials more responsive or accountable. In China, it is not uncommon for malfeasant or irresponsive local officials to be exempted by upper-level authorities despite citizens’ complaints or resistance. This is because, in addition to the financial resources needed to address citizens’ grievances, the disciplining of local state agencies or their officials is a sensitive political issue, and the political cost involved may deter upper-level authorities from doing so. As a result, many of the grievances sent by citizens through rightful resistance
may simply be ignored by upper-level state authorities.³⁶ This is the fundamental reason why the violation of citizens’ rights or the ignorance of citizens’ injustices by state authorities has recurred in China despite the enactment of laws or regulations.
One method for the disgruntled to prevent upper-level authorities from ignoring lower-level agents’ misconduct or irresponsiveness is to lower the political cost of discipline. Other things being equal, the upper-level authority is more willing to punish agents who have committed multiple acts of misconduct as opposed to those who have committed fewer. The authority is also more willing to punish those who have committed serious misconduct. When possible, protesters can highlight the multiple acts of misconduct of local officials, their serious misconduct, or even their crimes (e.g., corruption), although some of the misconduct may not be the causes of the protesters’ grievances. As a result, if local officials fail to address citizens’ grievances or try to repress their demands, the citizens can reveal or threaten to reveal local officials’ other types of malfeasance to upper-level authorities. This method of issue connection poses risks or threats to targeted officials because some of the reported misconduct may be seen as unacceptable by upper-level authorities, thereby triggering intervention. Consequently, those local officials who are worried about citizens’ reporting on their misconduct may be more responsive to the citizens’ grievances and even make concessions to silence them.
SEEKING SUPPORT FROM WITHIN THE STATE
A second way for resisters to achieve success in popular contention is to receive external support or to seek alliances in or outside the political system. Allies can provide resources and make the system more open to protest demands, thereby providing important aid to weak groups. Lipsky points out that the essence of political protest consists of activating third parties to participate in a controversy in ways that are favorable to the protest’s goals.³⁷ As a matter of fact, gaining external support has been seen as a precondition for weak groups’ success. Jenkins and Perrow argue: When deprived groups do mobilize, it is due to the interjection of external resources . . . Success comes when there is a combination of sustained outside support and disunity and/or tolerance on the part of political elites.
³⁸ This can be true for weak groups regardless of the political system.
In China, there may also be external support, such as media exposure, that provides significant help to the people in defense of their rights. Nevertheless, because the state controls political power and most political resources, seeking support from within the state is often necessary. This is also possible because the Chinese state is not monolithic, and there are differences not only between different levels of government but also between different state agencies at the same level. These differences imply that some state actors may be more receptive to the demands of the disgruntled than others will be. In other words, these differences may create latent opportunities for successful resistance, but participants have to activate such latent opportunities through effective means.
O’Brien and Li show that some state agents may support citizens’ claims because the enforcement of certain policies benefits their agencies.³⁹ At other times, an alliance with state agents may not be based on state agencies’ organizational interests. In Chinese society, where politics is less institutionalized than in well-established democracies, individuals have important influence in the operation of the political system. This creates the possibility for some citizens to generate support from within the state through personal networks. Chinese society is characterized by the permeation of personal connections, or guanxi, in social and political settings.⁴⁰ Therefore, an important channel through which the disgruntled seek support from inside the state is to mobilize their personal connections with people who have either political power (e.g., government officials) or political influence (e.g., journalists). Social networks or connections are important political assets of the citizens. Certainly, not all citizens have such connections, and their access to political resources based on networks may vary considerably.
STAGING FORCEFUL ACTION
Not all citizens whose interests are violated can gain extra leverage or obtain support from within the state, but some of these people may resort to more disruptive modes of action to succeed. Certainly, such success is also conditional. Piven and Cloward believe that to be ignored or punished is what the poor ordinarily expect from government.
⁴¹ This is the case because the costs and risks involved in repressing a weak target are small compared with those associated with the repression of a powerful opponent.⁴² By the same token, powerful or better-organized groups have enhanced opportunities. This helps to explain