The New Science of Asset Allocation: Risk Management in a Multi-Asset World
()
About this ebook
A feasible asset allocation framework for the post 2008 financial world
Asset allocation has long been a cornerstone of prudent investment management; however, traditional allocation plans failed investors miserably in 2008. Asset allocation still remains an essential part of the investment arena, and through a new approach, you'll discover how to make it work.
In The New Science of Asset Allocation, authors Thomas Schneeweis, Garry Crowder, and Hossein Kazemi first explore the myths that plague this field then quickly move on to examine how the practice of asset allocation has failed in recent years. They then propose new allocation models that employ liquidity, transparency, and real risk controls across multiple asset classes.
- Outlines a new approach to asset allocation in a post-2008 world, where risk seems hidden
- The "great manager" problem is examined with solutions on how to capture manager alpha while limiting downside risk
- A complete case study is presented that allocates for beta and alpha
Written by an experienced team of industry leaders and academic experts, The New Science of Asset Allocation explains how you can effectively apply this approach to a financial world that continues to change.
Related to The New Science of Asset Allocation
Titles in the series (100)
Risk Budgeting: Portfolio Problem Solving with Value-at-Risk Rating: 0 out of 5 stars0 ratingsAsian Financial Statement Analysis: Detecting Financial Irregularities Rating: 0 out of 5 stars0 ratingsBusiness Exit Planning: Options, Value Enhancement, and Transaction Management for Business Owners Rating: 5 out of 5 stars5/5The Exchange-Traded Funds Manual Rating: 0 out of 5 stars0 ratingsDebt Capital Markets in China Rating: 0 out of 5 stars0 ratingsThe Securitization Markets Handbook: Structures and Dynamics of Mortgage- and Asset-backed Securities Rating: 0 out of 5 stars0 ratingsThe Handbook for Investment Committee Members: How to Make Prudent Investments for Your Organization Rating: 0 out of 5 stars0 ratingsInvesting in Fixed Income Securities: Understanding the Bond Market Rating: 0 out of 5 stars0 ratingsInvestor's Guide to Loss Recovery: Rights, Mediation, Arbitration, and other Strategies Rating: 0 out of 5 stars0 ratingsThe Mechanics of Securitization: A Practical Guide to Structuring and Closing Asset-Backed Security Transactions Rating: 0 out of 5 stars0 ratingsFinancial Simulation Modeling in Excel: A Step-by-Step Guide Rating: 3 out of 5 stars3/5Private Equity: Transforming Public Stock to Create Value Rating: 0 out of 5 stars0 ratingsPrivate Equity: History, Governance, and Operations Rating: 0 out of 5 stars0 ratingsMiddle Market M & A: Handbook for Investment Banking and Business Consulting Rating: 4 out of 5 stars4/5Foreign Exchange: A Practical Guide to the FX Markets Rating: 5 out of 5 stars5/5Risk Transfer: Derivatives in Theory and Practice Rating: 0 out of 5 stars0 ratingsBehavioral Finance and Wealth Management: How to Build Optimal Portfolios That Account for Investor Biases Rating: 4 out of 5 stars4/5Investment Manager Analysis: A Comprehensive Guide to Portfolio Selection, Monitoring and Optimization Rating: 4 out of 5 stars4/5Performance Dashboards and Analysis for Value Creation Rating: 3 out of 5 stars3/5Equity Derivatives: Theory and Applications Rating: 3 out of 5 stars3/5A History of Interest Rates Rating: 3 out of 5 stars3/5Active Alpha: A Portfolio Approach to Selecting and Managing Alternative Investments Rating: 0 out of 5 stars0 ratingsOption Pricing Models and Volatility Using Excel-VBA Rating: 4 out of 5 stars4/5Active Value Investing: Making Money in Range-Bound Markets Rating: 3 out of 5 stars3/5Structured Finance and Insurance: The ART of Managing Capital and Risk Rating: 3 out of 5 stars3/5Implementing Enterprise Risk Management: From Methods to Applications Rating: 0 out of 5 stars0 ratingsValuation: Measuring and Managing the Value of Companies Rating: 3 out of 5 stars3/5International Corporate Governance After Sarbanes-Oxley Rating: 0 out of 5 stars0 ratingsPairs Trading: Quantitative Methods and Analysis Rating: 3 out of 5 stars3/5Modeling Structured Finance Cash Flows with Microsoft Excel: A Step-by-Step Guide Rating: 4 out of 5 stars4/5
Related ebooks
Systematic Investing in Credit Rating: 0 out of 5 stars0 ratingsModern Portfolio Management: Moving Beyond Modern Portfolio Theory Rating: 0 out of 5 stars0 ratingsActive Alpha: A Portfolio Approach to Selecting and Managing Alternative Investments Rating: 0 out of 5 stars0 ratingsTreynor On Institutional Investing Rating: 0 out of 5 stars0 ratingsFinancial Risk Management: Applications in Market, Credit, Asset and Liability Management and Firmwide Risk Rating: 0 out of 5 stars0 ratingsActive Credit Portfolio Management in Practice Rating: 0 out of 5 stars0 ratingsThe Handbook for Investment Committee Members: How to Make Prudent Investments for Your Organization Rating: 0 out of 5 stars0 ratingsRisk Budgeting: Portfolio Problem Solving with Value-at-Risk Rating: 0 out of 5 stars0 ratingsFixed Income Relative Value Analysis: A Practitioners Guide to the Theory, Tools, and Trades Rating: 0 out of 5 stars0 ratingsAdvanced Credit Risk Analysis and Management Rating: 4 out of 5 stars4/5Quantitative Equity Investing: Techniques and Strategies Rating: 4 out of 5 stars4/5Luxembourg Wealth Management Portfolio Management Rating: 0 out of 5 stars0 ratingsQuantitative Financial Risk Management Rating: 0 out of 5 stars0 ratingsDerivatives Workbook Rating: 0 out of 5 stars0 ratingsFinance: Mastering Finance, Your Guide to Financial Success Rating: 0 out of 5 stars0 ratingsQuantitative Risk Management: A Practical Guide to Financial Risk Rating: 0 out of 5 stars0 ratingsPension Revolution: A Solution to the Pensions Crisis Rating: 0 out of 5 stars0 ratingsManaging Credit Risk: The Great Challenge for Global Financial Markets Rating: 0 out of 5 stars0 ratingsInvestment Management Theory and Practical Rating: 0 out of 5 stars0 ratingsDerivatives Rating: 0 out of 5 stars0 ratingsAsset Allocation: From Theory to Practice and Beyond Rating: 0 out of 5 stars0 ratingsFinancial Risk Management: Models, History, and Institutions Rating: 5 out of 5 stars5/5Fixed Income Securities: Tools for Today's Markets Rating: 0 out of 5 stars0 ratingsThe Exchange-Traded Funds Manual Rating: 0 out of 5 stars0 ratingsEmerging Market Real Estate Investment: Investing in China, India, and Brazil Rating: 0 out of 5 stars0 ratingsA Practitioner's Guide to Asset Allocation Rating: 0 out of 5 stars0 ratingsInvesting in Fixed Income Securities: Understanding the Bond Market Rating: 0 out of 5 stars0 ratingsEquity Markets, Valuation, and Analysis Rating: 0 out of 5 stars0 ratingsIntroduction to Fixed Income Analytics: Relative Value Analysis, Risk Measures and Valuation Rating: 0 out of 5 stars0 ratings
Investments & Securities For You
Principles: Life and Work Rating: 4 out of 5 stars4/5How to Invest: Masters on the Craft Rating: 4 out of 5 stars4/5Technical Analysis For Dummies Rating: 5 out of 5 stars5/5Stock Market Investing for Beginners & Dummies Rating: 5 out of 5 stars5/5Just Keep Buying: Proven ways to save money and build your wealth Rating: 5 out of 5 stars5/5Stock Investing For Dummies Rating: 5 out of 5 stars5/5Girls That Invest: Your Guide to Financial Independence through Shares and Stocks Rating: 5 out of 5 stars5/5The Little Book of Common Sense Investing: The Only Way to Guarantee Your Fair Share of Stock Market Returns Rating: 4 out of 5 stars4/5Investing For Beginners: Introduction to Investing, #1 Rating: 4 out of 5 stars4/5How to Day Trade: The Plain Truth Rating: 5 out of 5 stars5/5Day Trading For Dummies Rating: 4 out of 5 stars4/5A Beginner's Guide To Day Trading Online 2nd Edition Rating: 4 out of 5 stars4/5Best Loser Wins: Why Normal Thinking Never Wins the Trading Game – written by a high-stake day trader Rating: 5 out of 5 stars5/5The Intelligent Investor Summary Rating: 4 out of 5 stars4/5Technical Analysis A Newbies' Guide: Trading Stocks with Simple Strategies Using Technical Analysis Rating: 4 out of 5 stars4/5Options Trading Crash Course: The #1 Beginner's Guide to Make Money with Trading Options in 7 Days or Less! Rating: 4 out of 5 stars4/5Reading Price Charts Bar by Bar: The Technical Analysis of Price Action for the Serious Trader Rating: 5 out of 5 stars5/5Swing Trading using the 4-hour chart 1-3: 3 Manuscripts Rating: 5 out of 5 stars5/5Options Trading For Dummies Rating: 0 out of 5 stars0 ratingsFinancial Statement Basics: From Confusion to Comfort in Under 100 Pages Rating: 4 out of 5 stars4/5Cryptocurrency: Beginners Bible - How You Can Make Money Trading and Investing in Cryptocurrency Rating: 4 out of 5 stars4/5Cryptocurrency Investing For Dummies Rating: 5 out of 5 stars5/5Fundamental Analysis For Dummies Rating: 5 out of 5 stars5/5
Reviews for The New Science of Asset Allocation
0 ratings0 reviews
Book preview
The New Science of Asset Allocation - Thomas Schneeweis
CHAPTER 1
A Brief History of Asset Allocation
For most investors, asset allocation and its meaning seems relatively straightforward, that is, the process of allocating assets. It is the how and the why of asset allocation that has led to an entire asset management industry dedicated to its operation. Given the amount of resources and effort dedicated to understanding asset allocation, it would be reasonable to expect that after almost 5,000 years of human history there would be a suitable solution. The fact that the investment management industry is still groping for an answer is illustrated in the millions of references to asset allocation
from any Internet search and the fact that there are enough practitioner books and academic articles on how to allocate assets
to fill any investor’s library. This chapter provides a brief history of how major advances in financial theory and investment practice affected investors’ approach to asset allocation and how asset allocation has had to evolve to meet changes in economic, regulatory, and technological environments. However, given the range of current and past efforts to diagnose, describe, and prescribe the process of asset allocation, it seems relatively futile to provide any reasonable summary of how we got here, much less what here
is.
Before reviewing how we have arrived at current approaches to asset allocation, a brief review of what asset allocation is seems appropriate. Simply put, the ability to estimate what the future returns and risks of a range of investors’ acceptable investments are and to choose a course of action based upon those alternatives is at the heart of asset allocation. As a result, much of asset allocation is centered on the quantitative tools or approaches used to estimate the probabilities of what may happen (risk) and the alternative approaches to managing that risk (risk management). While the concept of risk is multi-dimensional—including various types of market risks as well as liquidity risk, operational risk, legal risk, counterparty risk, and so on—for many it is simply the probability of a bad outcome. There is simply no single approach to asset allocation that covers all individuals’ sense of risk tolerance or even what risk is. In the world of asset allocation, we generally concentrate on the concept of statistically driven risk management since those risk measurements are often centered on statistical estimates of probability (which is measurable) rather than on the concept of uncertainty (or possibility management), on which our empirically driven asset allocation models have little to say.
As a consequence, there is risk or uncertainty even in the most basic concept of asset allocation. Much of what we do in asset allocation is based on the tradeoffs between the risks and returns of various investable assets as well as the risks and returns of various aspects of asset allocation, including alternative approaches to return and risk estimation. Choosing among the various courses of action lies at the heart of a wide range of asset allocation approaches, including:
• Strategic asset management (allocation across various investment classes with the goal of achieving a desired long-term risk exposure)
• Tactical asset management (allocation within or across investment classes with the goal of maximizing the portfolio ’s short-term returnrisk profile)
• Dynamic asset management (systematic changes in allocation across assets with the goal of fundamentally changing the portfolio’s risk exposure in a predetermined way)
Asset allocation is not about solely maximizing expected return. It is a central thesis of this book as well as years of academic theory and investment practice that expected return is a function of the risks taken and that those risks may not be able to be measured or managed solely through systematic algorithmic based risk management. Thus, asset allocation must focus on risk management in a broader context, including the benefit of an individual asset allocators’s discretionary oversight in order to provide a suitable return to risk tradeoff consistent with an investor’s risk tolerance or investment goals. The story of the evolution of our understanding of that return to risk tradeoff is the subject of this chapter. It is important to emphasize the evolution
part as our understanding of the expected return to risk relationship keeps changing. First, because through time we learn more about how individuals react to risk and second, because the world itself changes (the financial world included).¹
An individual’s or institution’s approach to asset allocation depends of course in part on their relative understanding of the alternative approaches and the underlying risks and returns of each. For the most part, this book does not attempt to depict the results of the most current research on various approaches to asset allocation. In many cases, that research has not undergone a full review or critical analysis and is often based solely on algorithmic based model building. Also, many individuals are simply not aware of or at ease with this current research since their investment background is often rooted in traditional investment books in which much of this current research
is not included.²
IN THE BEGINNING
It should be of no surprise to investors that the two fundamental directives of asset allocation: (1) estimate what may happen and (2) choose a course of action based on those estimates have been at the core of practitioner and academic debate. For our purposes, the timeline of that debate is illustrated in Exhibit 1.1. The advent of Modern Portfolio Theory and practice is often linked to the publication of Harry Markowitz’s 1952 article Portfolio Selection.
For many the very words Modern Portfolio Theory
are synonymous with Markowitz. It is important to point out that Modern Portfolio Theory is now almost 60 years old. As such, and not merely as a result of age, MPT (Modern Portfolio Theory) is really IPT (Initial Portfolio Theory) or OPT (Old Portfolio Theory). Moreover, the fundamental concept expressed in Markowitz’s article (the ability to manage risk based on the expected correlation relationships between assets) was well known by practitioners at the time of its publication.
EXHIBIT 1.1 Timeline of Financial Advances in Asset Allocation
002Markowitz formalized the return and risk relationship between securities in what is known today as the mathematics of diversification. If expected single-period returns and standard deviations of available securities as well as the correlations among them are estimated, then the standard deviation and the expected return of any portfolio consisting of those securities can be calculated. This means that portfolios can be constructed with desirable standard deviation and expected return profiles. One particular set of such portfolios is the so-called mean-variance efficient portfolios, which have the highest expected rate of return for a given level of risk (variance). The collection of such portfolios for various levels of variance leads to the mean - variance efficient frontier.³ In the mid 1950s, James Tobin (1958) expanded on Markowitz’s work by adding a risk-free asset to the analysis.⁴ This brought into focus an individual ’s ability to hold only two types of assets (risky and riskless) and to lend or borrow such that those two assets provided the tools necessary to match a wide range of investor return and risk preferences.⁵
The next major advancement in asset allocation expanded the work of Markowitz and Tobin into a general equilibrium model of risk and return. In this work, academics treated volatility and expected return as proxies for risk and reward. In the early 1960s, academics (Sharpe, 1964) proposed a theoretical relationship between expected return and risk based on a set of assumptions of individual behavior and market conditions. These author(s) proposed that if investors invested in the mean -variance efficient market portfolio, then the required rate of return of an individual security would be directly related to its marginal contribution to the volatility of that mean-variance efficient market portfolio; that is, the risk of a security (and therefore its expected return) could not be determined while ignoring its role in a diversified portfolio.
A REVIEW OF THE CAPITAL ASSET PRICING MODEL
The model developed by Sharpe and others is known as the Capital Asset Pricing Model (CAPM). While the results of this model are based on several unrealistic assumptions, it has dominated the world of finance and asset allocation for the past 40 years. The main foundation of the CAPM is that regardless of their risk-return preference, all investors can create desirable mean-variance efficient portfolios by combining two portfolios/assets: One is a unique, highly diversified, mean-variance efficient portfolio (market portfolio) and the other is the riskless asset. By combining these two investments, investors should be able to create mean-variance efficient portfolios that match their risk preferences. The combination of the riskless asset and the market portfolio (the Capital Market Line [CML] as shown in Exhibit 1.2) provides a solution to the asset allocation problem in a very simple and intuitive manner: Just combine the market portfolio with riskless asset and you will create a portfolio that has optimal risk -return properties.
In such a world, the risk of an individual security is then measured by its marginal contribution to the volatility (risk) of the market portfolio. This leads to the so -called CAPM:
003where
Rf = Return on the riskless asset
E(Rm) and E(Ri) = Expected returns on the market portfolio and
a security
σm and σ i = Standard deviations of the market portfolio
and the security
Corr(Ri, Rm) = Correlation between the market portfolio and
the security
EXHIBIT 1.2 Capital Market Line
004EXHIBIT 1.3 Security Market Line
005Thus, in the world of the CAPM all the assets are theoretically located on the same straight line that passes through the point representing the market portfolio with beta equal to 1. That line is called the Security Market Line (SML), as shown in Exhibit 1.3. The basic difference between the CML and the SML is one of reference system. In the CML the risk measured is total risk (standard deviation), while the risk measured in the SML is a security’s marginal risk to the market portfolio (beta).
While the most basic messages of MPT and CAPM (that diversification is important and that risk has to be measured in the context of an asset ’s marginal contribution to the risk of reference market portfolio) are valid and accepted widely by both academics and practitioners, many of their specific recommendations and predictions are not yet fully accepted and in some cases have been rejected by empirical evidence.⁶ For instance, observed security returns are very weakly, if at all, related to a security ’s beta, and most investors find a simple combination of the market portfolio and the riskless asset totally inadequate in meeting their risk-return requirements.
ASSET PRICING IN CASH AND DERIVATIVE MARKETS
CAPM and EMH
As discussed in greater detail later in this book, the CAPM profoundly shaped how asset allocation within and across asset classes was first conducted. Individual assets could be priced using a limited set of parameters. Securities could be grouped by their common market sensitivity into different risk classes and evaluated accordingly; and, to the degree that an expected market risk premia could be modeled, it would also be possible (if desired) to adjust the underlying risk or beta of a portfolio to take advantage of changes in expected market risk premia (i.e., increase the beta of the portfolio if expected market risk premia is high and reduce the beta of the portfolio if the expected market risk premia is low). Here, market risk premia is defined as the difference between the expected rate of return of the market portfolio and the riskless rate of interest.
While the CAPM is at its heart a model of expected return determination, it quickly became the basis for a number of asset allocation based decision models. The rudimentary nature of computers in the early 1960s is often forgotten and, while the mathematics of the Markowitz portfolio optimization model were well known, the practical application was limited due primarily to the number of numerical calculations. Specifically, the amount of data needed to obtain reasonable estimates of the covariance matrix is significant. For instance, if we have 100 securities, then to estimate the covariance matrix, we would need to estimate 100 variances and (100² - 100)/2 covariances, which add up to 5,050 parameters, have to be estimated. This would be computationally difficult and would have required many hours of work. As an alternative, the number of calculations can be significantly reduced if it is assumed that returns are driven by only one factor (e.g., the market portfolio). Note that this does not assume that CAPM holds. In other words, suppose we use a simple linear regression to estimate the beta of an asset with respect to a well diversified portfolio.
Rit = αi + βi Rmt + eit
The rate of return on the asset at time t is given by Rit, the rate of return on the diversified portfolio is given by Rmt, the intercept and the slope (beta) are given by α i and β i respectively. Finally, the error term for asset i is given by eit. Suppose we run the same regression for another asset, denoted asset j. If the error term for asset j is uncorrelated with the error term for asset i, then the covariance between the two assets is given by
Cov (Ri , Rj ) = βi β jVar (Rm )
Notice that to estimate covariance between the two assets, we need an estimate of the variance of the market portfolio as well (Var(Rm)). However, this term will be common to all estimates of covariance. The result is that the number calculations required to estimate covariance matrix is now reduced to (2 × 100 + 1).
It is important to note that the above regression model, known as the market model, has nothing to do with the CAPM. The above regression makes no prediction about the size or the sign of intercept. It simply a statistical relationship used to estimate the beta. On the other hand, the CAPM predicts that the market model intercept will be (1 - βi)Rf.
It is fair to say, however, that almost 40 years ago most academics and professionals knew that the CAPM was an incomplete
model of expected return. We now know that Sharpe and his fellow academics had unwittingly created a sort of Asset Pricing Vampire,
which rose from their model and, despite 30 years of stakes driven into its heart lives to this day for many practitioners as the primary approach to return estimation.⁷ In the early years of the CAPM, financial economists were like kids with a new hammer in which everything in the financial world looked like a nail. For example, if an asset’s expected return can be estimated, then that estimate could be used as a basis for determining if an individual could consistently choose assets that were fundamentally underpriced and offered an ex post return greater than that consistent with its underlying risk. In sum, it provided the basis for determining if managers could obtain an alpha (excess return above that consistent with the expected return of a similar risk - passive investable asset).
The combination of the full information assumptions in the CAPM, along with the presumed
ability to measure expected returns consistent with risk, offered academics the chance to measure the true informational efficiency of the marketplace. Initial studies by academics indicated that active managers underperformed similar risk passive indices. This empirical result helped give rise later to the creation of a series of passive non-investable and investable indices that would form the basis for the asset allocation consulting industry. As important, the combination of presumed informational efficiency with the ability to measure expected return led to the development of the Efficient Market Hypothesis (Fama, 1970) in which assets’ prices were described relative to the degree to which their current prices reflected various types of information; that is, an asset’s current price may be consistent with (1) past price information (weak form efficiency); (2) public information (semi-strong efficiency); and (3) private information (strong form efficiency). If market inefficiencies existed, this implied that investors could earn returns that would exceed what is predicted by the asset’s underlying risk as if there were some violation of information efficiency (similar to a monopoly or oligopolies). However, if the Efficient Market Hypothesis (EMH) is true, most investors should not waste their time trying to pick individual stocks using well-known public information but concentrate on risk determination and the proper set of assets to capture the expected risk that matches their risk preferences.
Today it is realized that the Efficient Market Hypothesis would be more correctly named the Excess Return if We Only Knew How To Measure Expected Return Hypothesis
; it did provide the impetus for moving from a Managers Only Matter
state of mind to an asset allocation process based on Managers May Matter But Let Us Measure It First
plus a Passive Approach to Asset Class/Security Selection.
Again, it is important to come to terms with what the EMH says and does not say. EMH does not say that prices fluctuate randomly. EMH states that prices randomly fluctuate with a drift; that is, tomorrow’s expected price is equal to today’s price times the asset’s expected return where expected return is based on current information (risk assessment). EMH says that there are no free lunches. Such profit opportunities are quickly eliminated, and the only way one can earn a high rate of return is through assuming a higher level of risk.
The quintessential problem is that there is no firm understanding of how people determine expected risk-adjusted return since there are no conclusive models that demonstrate how people price risk. All we can say is whether a manager has been able to create excess return (return above some arbitrary chosen expected return model). The EMH does not say that an investment manager cannot make a gross return in excess of a passive approach. The EMH only says that if a manager makes such an excess return (e.g., because of access to technology or information), the investor may be charged a fee equal to the excess return such that the net return will be similar to that of investment in the passive index (e.g., manager returns - manager fee ≥ return on passive index). The manager’s fee is supposed to cover the cost of acquiring the technology and/or information plus the investment made in time and effort to use that technology and information.
The combination of the CAPM and the EMH gave the market place the twin academic pillars required for the development of the asset allocation industry. All that was needed was a third pillar, a business model capable of developing the infrastructure required to market this new industry. Fortunately, computers and information technology had advanced such that in the late 1960s the investment industry witnessed the expansion of the index business. Both within the United States and overseas, monthly and even daily data series of domestic and global stock indices were being created. These indices could be used to provide estimates of the benefits of various approaches to asset allocation. For instance, newly developed global stock indices were used in a number of studies to illustrate the potential benefits of combining domestic stock indices (asset classes) with foreign and international stock indices (Grubel, 1968; Levy and Sarnet, 1970).⁸
Lost, of course, in this academic and practitioner euphoria were some of the practical realities relating to the underlying assumptions of the CAPM and EMH. First, the available empirical evidence had not strictly supported the CAPM’s expected return and risk relationship. There was no means to estimate the True Market Portfolio,
so any empirically estimated betas were only estimates subject to unknown measurement errors. More complex multi-factor models were required to capture expected return processes. While the market for financial products aimed at providing such multi-factor models came into existence (e.g., Barr Rosenberg and Barr’s better betas), most academics remained wedded to single -factor models. As academics came to appreciate the statistical problems associated with using underspecified single factor (beta) models of return determination or the data problems associated with the use of international data (e.g., timing of data or liquidity), attempts were made to tweak
the CAPM. Throughout the 1970s, various forms of zero beta and multi -beta APT models came into existence—better to explain the previously unexplained residual error of the single factor models of return estimation. These models provided additional statistical tools for measuring the efficacy of the EMH.
As with most people, when given the choice between the familiar and the unfamiliar, academics and practitioners kept using the hammers they had (CAPM and EMH) to nail down the problem of expected return estimation and the degree to which individual managers provided returns in excess of similar risk passively produced portfolio returns. In truth, the CAPM and EMH models did an excellent job of describing most market conditions. For the most part, markets do work. It should be expected that for financial markets with low-cost information (e.g., Treasury Bill market), asset prices would reflect current information and a common risk based return model. Other markets and/or assets may require enlarged risk based factor models that capture an enlarged set of underlying risks and therefore expected returns. Small firms with few analysts following them, with less ability to raise capital, with a less diversified client base, limited legal support, and so on may be priced to reflect those risks. Many assets are simply not tradable or have high transaction costs (e.g., housing, commodities, employment contracts, or distressed debt). How they could or should be priced in a single-factor or even a multi-factor model framework was explored, but a solution was rarely found.⁹
Option Pricing Models and Growth of Futures Markets
We have spent a great deal of time focusing on the equity markets. During this period of market innovation, considerable research also centered on direct arbitrage relationships. Arbitrage relationships in capital and corporate markets were explored during the 1930s (forward interest rates implied in yield curve models)¹⁰ and in the 1950s (corporate dividend policy and debt policy). Similarly, cost of carry arbitrage models had long been the focal point of pricing in most futures based research. In the early 1970s Fischer Black and Myron Scholes (1973) and Merton (1973) developed a simple-to-use option pricing model based in part on arbitrage relationships between investment vehicles. Soon after, fundamental arbitrage between the relative prices of a put option (the right to sell) and a call option (the right to buy) formed a process to become known as the Put-Call Parity Model, which provided a means to explain easily the various ways options can be used to modify the underlying risk characteristics of existing portfolios. Exchange based trading floors soon came into existence, which helped eventually to develop a market for a wide range of option based financial derivatives. While a range of dynamic futures based approaches should provide similar risk management opportunities, options provided a direct and easily measured approach to fundamentally change the risk composition of an asset or a portfolio. As important, the model allowed one to estimate the cost for modifying the risk of a portfolio.
The growth of options as a means to provide risk management was centered primarily on equity markets. The 1970s also witnessed the creation and growth of new forms of financial futures, including currency futures in the early part of that decade and various forms of fixed income futures in the latter half (Treasury Bond futures). The creation of the Commodity Futures Trading Commission (CFTC) in the mid 1970s provided the additional government oversight necessary for the growth and development of new forms of financial futures as well as options products based on them. It is well known that futures provide a means to directly track underlying investment markets as well as to provide risk reduction opportunities. Futures contracts offer the ability to reduce or increase the underlying variability of an asset but futures alone do not permit one to fundamentally change the risk structure of the asset. The ability to directly change the distributional form of an asset is left for options. It can simply be said that the creation and development of options and futures trading in the 1970s led the way for the creation of an entire new industry dedicated to new means of managing risk.
MODELS OF RETURN AND RISK POST-1980
Models of investors’ behavior as well as models of return and risk relationships, like so much of modern finance as well as life, are evolutionary. Given the tools and information at hand, various theories of expected return and risk relationships were put forth and were tested against the available data and technology of the period. Whether realized or not, none of the theories presented offered stopping points. They were in fact evolutionary steps with each reaching a conclusion within the confines of their stated parameters. As noted above, the EMH only states that expected return is a function of expected risk, which is a function of expected information. Nothing says that individuals do not get it wrong ex post or even that they had it right ex ante. In any market there is a process of information discovery and market reaction. The fact that, on average, individuals do not correctly value factors such as ratings or real estate payment